As the European Union’s Capital Market Union Action Plan1 puts forward, deeper and integrated capital markets promise to provide businesses with a greater choice of funding at lower cost and offer new investment opportunities for investors. Law has an important role to play in expanding investment choice and in minimising the cost of finance. This concerns both equity and debt finance. The role of the law in corporate finance is two-fold. First, it can enable financial arrangements that parties would have trouble creating based only on freedom of contract. An example is the provision of different classes of shares by company law. Second, it can contribute to reducing the cost of business finance. An example is finding the right balance between creditor protection and flexibility for shareholders in capital restructurings. If creditors are prone to expropriation, the cost of debt finance will rise. At the same time, overly limiting shareholder flexibility will make equity finance more costly. The latter shows that legal reform should keep in mind that market actors will react to the corporate finance framework they find. If the law does not create the optimal balance, equity and/or debt investors will charge a premium for the finance provided. As a consequence, fewer projects and businesses would be financed. Hence, the ultimate goal should be to minimise the average cost of both equity and debt finance.
The stakeholder interviews in Latvia revealed a general consensus that updating core provisions of classic corporate finance law would be beneficial to support business finance. Providing investors and managers with finance options and clarity of law would put them in a position to develop innovative solutions. Hence, the starting point for an innovative finance practice can be high-quality core provisions of business finance law. In this regard, the Latvian Commercial Law already provides a stable basis. Stakeholders suggested to further broaden the range of finance options available and provide businesses with more certainty.
A minor, but potential helpful change called for by stakeholders is to allow the nominal value of shares to be determined in cents. Currently, Section 186(1) of the Latvian Commercial Law requires the nominal value of equity capital of a private company to be expressed in whole euros. Consequently, a nominal value of one cent or ten cents is prohibited for private companies. The nominal value of a share in a public company may not be less than ten cents according to Section 230(2) of the Latvian Commercial Law. These restrictions for private and public companies may complicate certain forms of sophisticated business participation. Lower amounts may become necessary after incorporation, for example to implement the introduction of new classes of shares or capital restructurings. Allowing one-cent shares for both private and public companies in Latvia - as a possibility - could increase the flexibility for businesses to arrange their finance structure, as there seems to be low risk this would lead to costs or further problems in legal reality.
A further basic feature of shares that might be discussed is the introduction of no par value shares, i.e. shares without a nominal value. The shares of both private and public companies are required to have a fixed nominal (or par) value, according to Section 186(1) of the Latvian Commercial Law. There is a trend in many countries to move away from a mandatory nominal value of shares as they are often associated with complications in share capital adjustments and could lead to confusion for market participants. Countries that allow no par value shares are, for example, Australia, Germany, Portugal and South Africa. While non par value shares may be attractive for businesses and their investors, they require careful drafting when reforming the law. One of the options to consider for Latvia is to offer businesses a choice between nominal (par) and no par value shares. This is the approach that the German Aktiengesetz currently takes.
Another possibility asked for by stakeholders is to facilitate the creation of classes of shares in private companies. The Latvian Commercial Law recognises the possibility of creating different classes of shares in Section 227. This provision, however, is to be found in the rules for public companies. As a result, the question arose whether different classes of shares can be created for private companies. While the Latvian Commercial Law does not contain a prohibition to create different share classes in private companies, the uncertainty regarding class rights created by the current law is often reported to create problems for private companies. Similar to some OECD countries (e.g., Germany, United States and the United Kingdom), Latvia may encourage the freedom for businesses and their equity investors to create different classes of shares, with different classes allowing the possibility to offer different equity participation to different types of investors. As there are different types of investors with different types of investment interests and profiles in the market, more flexibility in terms of share classes may encourage more equity investment at lower cost. The rise of start-up finance and private equity finance in the United States and the United Kingdom was – among other things – based on the ability of their legal systems to provide different share classes in private companies.
The logic that class rights are a means to satisfy the investment interests of different types of equity investors with the expectation that this will lead to more equity finance offered at lower cost may also call for a reconsideration of the regulation of class rights for public companies. The rules on class rights in Section 227 of the Latvian Commercial Law currently seem to limit the type of class rights that can be created. This section only mentions different rights with respect to: 1) receiving dividends; 2) receiving a liquidation quota; and 3) voting rights at a meeting of stockholders. Consequently, it seems that all other types of class rights are not recognised by Latvian law. However, investors and companies may have good reasons to provide certain shares with other types of administrative, financial or information rights. The occasion of looking into the issue of class rights for private companies might be combined with reconsidering a more liberal approach to the definition of classes of shares. One solution might be to do away with the enumeration of different types of class rights and instead only define what constitutes a class of shares. It would then be left to the businesses and their investors to negotiate the types of class rights that fit their needs. This approach is currently taken both by English and German company law.
Similar considerations concern the regulation of preference shares. Preference shares are regulated in Sections 231 to 234 of the Latvian Commercial Law. Further provisions concern the position of preference shareholders, in particular in reorganisation. First, the fact that Sections 231 and following of the Latvian Commercial Law only apply to public companies raised the concern of several stakeholders that preference shares might be considered unavailable to private companies. At the least, even if registers and courts accept preference shares in private companies, their position is fraught with uncertainty, which increases the cost of capital. Second, a number of stakeholders suggested deregulating the rules on preference shares. Section 232(1) of the Latvian Commercial Law leaves it to the articles of association to determine the rights of preference shares. However, stakeholders felt that the following subsections limit the freedom to create preference shares that fit their needs. In particular, subsection (3) determines that preferences with special dividend rights acquire voting rights only if dividends are not paid for two successive accounting years. It was suggested to consider deregulation of the law on preference shares and generally allow the shareholders to determine the rights associated with preference shares. In addition, stakeholders felt that there is scope to simplify the currently drawn-out procedure for voiding preference shares.
A further related issue is the facilitation of employee share schemes. The Latvian Commercial Law provides rules on employee shares only for public companies in Section 255. Stakeholders have expressed that this creates uncertainty on whether employee shares can be used in private companies. Employee shares can play a useful role for private companies, in particular to provide equity-based incentives. Going beyond the reduced applicability of Section 255 of the Latvian Commercial Law, thought might be given to equipping employee shares in general with further benefits. English law, for example, provides the following benefits for employee share schemes: 1) as a default position, directors do not require specific authority to allot employee shares; 2) pre-emption rights do not apply to employee shares; 3) a public company is not prevented from giving financial assistance for the acquisition of shares for an employee share scheme; 4) the rules on share buy-backs are less strict for employee shares. As a related side note, stakeholders also suggested the general relaxation of the rules on share buy-backs.
Moving on to exit options, it might be worthwhile discussing the costs and benefits of the right of first refusal in Section 189 of the Latvian Commercial Law. This area of law has been the focus of recent reform. According to section 189 of the Latvian Commercial Law, the other shareholders have a right of first refusal if a shareholder in a private company sells his or her shares. While such a rule can found in some cases, it might reduce the attraction of being a shareholder in a private company. The obligation to offer shares to the other shareholders after entering into a purchase agreement may create uncertainty for the original share purchase agreements and make the sale of shares in a private company a lengthy process. As a result, shareholders interested in exiting private companies will find it more difficult to find a buyer willing to incur the costs for a share purchase that might not happen in the end. This in turn may add further difficulties to the already reduced exit options regarding private companies. If investors know that exit is difficult, they might refrain from investing in the first place. Therefore, equity finance for private companies can become more costly and scarce. In English and German law a right of first refusal does not exist as a default position in private company law. The shareholders are always free to negotiate such a right for their company and establish it in the articles of association. Latvia might benefit from monitoring how the practice as regards the right of first refusal develops over time and consider adjustments, if this seems beneficial.
A final brief point concerns tax law although it is generally not within the ambit of this report. It might be interesting to note, though, that stakeholders asked to reconsider the point in time at which profit accrues in terms of tax law for share options. Choosing the point in time when they are exercised rather than when they are issued might make them more attractive in practice.