Sweden is a well-developed, knowledge-based economy that produces innovative, IP‑intense products. This is supported by existing indicators. In 2016, Swedish gross domestic product (GDP) per capita amounted SEK 408 333 (USD 49 000), above the OECD average (SEK 354 166 or USD 42 500). In terms of IP intensity, Swedish IP‑intensive industries contributed on average to 39.1% of the Swedish gross domestic product (GDP) (42.3% for the European Union [EU]) and accounted for 31.8% of employment in Sweden (27.8% for the EU) between 2011 and 2013 (EUIPO/EPO, 2016). Concerning trademarks, Sweden is the 8th country in the EU in terms of the total number of trademarks registered. Between 2011 and 2013, Swedish trademark-intensive industries contributed to 32.4% of the Swedish GDP and to 24.5% of employment in Sweden (EUIPO/EPO, 2016).
Swedish competitiveness relies on high levels of education, and on intense investments in all sorts of intellectual assets including research and development (see OECD, 2016). In 2016, the Swedish research and development spending represented 3.3% of GDP, a level higher than the OECD average (2.3%) or the United States (2.7%) and Japan (3.1%).
Sweden is also a highly globalised economy and characterised by the internationalisation of large Swedish companies and excellent integration in global value chains. Swedish exports, including engines and other machines, motor vehicles and telecommunications equipment, accounted for almost 45% of GDP in 2016. The Swedish exports intensity is largely above the OECD average (28%). These top exporting manufacturing industries in Sweden are in particular highly IPR-intensive. In addition, Sweden is a significant contributor to global value chains: in 2015, the Swedish exports represented more than 0.6% of total world exports in value-added terms (see OECD Trade in Value Added database).
To reiterate, the Swedish economy is well-developed, innovative and intellectual property (IP)-intense. It is also well integrated into the global economy through active participation in global value chains. These characteristics make Sweden particularly susceptible to the damaging effects of counterfeiting and piracy. This is especially relevant when the threats of counterfeiting and piracy are growing worldwide (OECD/EUIPO, 2019).
According to the OECD/EUIPO (2019), Sweden belongs to the top 15 countries whose companies are most affected by counterfeiting. In 2016, Sweden ranks 12th on the list of economies whose right holders suffer from counterfeiting. This means that 1% of the total seized value of fake goods worldwide concerned goods infringing Swedish IP.
The damaging effects of trade in counterfeit and pirated goods on the Swedish economy are analysed in this study from two perspectives:
1. the effects of smuggling of counterfeit products into Sweden
2. the effects of infringements of IP rights of Swedish right holders in world trade.
Regarding smuggling of fakes into Sweden, it will impact four areas analysed in this report: i) loss of consumers’ welfare; ii) loss of sales; iii) loss of jobs for the retail and wholesale sector; and iv) lower tax revenues. These four categories are described in detail in Chapter 2.
With respect to global trade in counterfeit and pirated products that infringe Swedish IPRs, it impacts the following areas described in Chapter 3: i) lower sales for IPR owners; ii) job losses for the Swedish manufacturing industries; and iii) lower tax revenues.
The methodological framework developed to calculate all these effects as well as the data used is presented below and discussed in detail in Annex A. Importantly, this framework takes account the “double-counting” issue, which arises from the sale of fake products in Sweden that infringe the IPRs of its own residents.
Chapter 4 summarises the main findings of the report and provides suggestions for future research.
Three important things should be kept in mind when analysing these impacts:
First, the methodology refers to the notion of primary and secondary markets for counterfeit and pirated goods. That is to say, it distinguishes between fake products that deceive consumers (primary markets) and those that are openly sold as fakes to consumers (secondary markets – see OECD/EUIPO, 2016). The markets for deceptive and non-deceptive products have significantly different characteristics, and these differences have important implications in the overall assessment.
Second, whereas in primary markets consumers pay the full (or approximately full) retail price for a fake product thinking it is genuine, consumers knowingly purchasing IPR-infringing products in secondary markets are likely to pay a lower price and would not necessarily have substituted the fakes for the genuine goods given the choice. Obviously, these differences in price and substitution rates have different implications for estimating lost sales and lost taxes, and for the valuation of consumer detriment (the price premium unjustly paid by consumers in the belief they are buying a genuine product).2
Third, there are other impact areas that are hard to measure quantitatively or are likely to occur only in the long term; these are therefore excluded from the analysis. They include, for example, the negative effects of counterfeiting and piracy on consumer health and safety, on the environment, on the proliferation of criminal networks and on long-term innovation and growth.