This chapter presents options to address the financial challenge through a multi-pronged approach. It sets out the key components of the enabling environment for investment, consisting of policies, regulations and institutional arrangements for both the water and the financial sector. It highlights the need for making the best use of existing sources of finance and assets to minimise overall investment needs. Finally, the chapter discusses how strategic investment planning can help to optimise future investment needs, including through nature-based solutions.
Financing a Water Secure Future
3. Options to address the financing challenge
Abstract
Mobilising capital for investment in water security requires urgent attention and action. Ensuring that water-related expenditures deliver value for money and tangible benefits in terms of water security and sustainable growth matters as well.
The scale of investment needs is a testament to inadequacy of prevailing policies, financing strategies and mechanisms. Public finance (supplemented by official development assistance in developing countries), although an essential contribution to financial sustainability of the sector, is not available at scale to cover current and projected investment needs. Moreover, individual investments and projects must form part of a robust pathway towards a resilient water management system if the multiple benefits are to materialise.
The challenge is not merely about mobilising more capital. A multi-pronged approach is required. Four key action areas discussed in turn below can guide efforts to improve the effectiveness and efficiency of water-related investments.
3.1. Strengthen the enabling environment for investment
3.1.1. Why a strong enabling environment is needed to facilitate investment
It is widely recognised that the water sector needs robust public policy and institutional frameworks to function effectively, given the common pool nature of water resources and the public good dimensions of selected water policies and services (OECD, 2019[1]). Such frameworks also have a profound influence on the water sector’s attractiveness to investors and its ability to recover costs and secure sustainable financing. As noted above and further examined in Chapter 4, the huge investment needs of the water sector over the coming decades demand increased volumes of sustainable finance drawn from a more diverse range of public and private sources (Money, 2017[2]; Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]; OECD, 2019[4]). To meet the financing challenge, governments should consider how existing policies and institutions might be enabling or impeding water-related investments.
A strong enabling environment for water-related investment can be broadly characterised as a set of policies, regulations and institutional arrangements that facilitate investment in activities that contribute to water security. This includes sector-specific policies, regulations and institutional arrangements as well as those relating to the regulation of the financial sector and capital markets. Well-designed policies and institutions are important for not only attracting investors, but also for ensuring that individual investments deliver their intended benefits and contribute to the sustainable financing and management of water resources and the delivery of water and sanitation services. Such conditions can therefore also play a pivotal role in minimising countries’ water-related investment needs over the long term, by contributing to policy coherence and ensuring the sector adapts to changing conditions, including climate change. A robust enabling environment is critical for allowing governments and investors to situate individual investments within their broader policy context, and to develop new projects and markets not as isolated, standalone investments conducted for their own sake, but instead as part of a holistic approach to achieving water policy aims (OECD, 2020[5]). Further, clearly defined policy orientations for water-related investment help governments to articulate both the benefits and the risks of different investment proposals (World Bank, 2017[6]).
By assessing the policy and institutional arrangements that create the settings for water-related investments, governments and investors can adopt a systemic perspective on the financing challenge and identify how such frameworks may be supporting or undermining efforts to scale up and diversify finance for the water sector. This applies to both public and private finance sources, but is especially critical in the context of efforts to secure commercial finance; the enabling environment can be a key determinant in the creditworthiness of potential borrowers and the “bankability” of proposed water projects (Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]; Streeter, 2017[7]).
This section examines various components of the enabling environment for investment to identify some of the main levers of influence available to governments seeking to increase water-related investment. These include the evaluation of policy settings (legal and regulatory, economic and financial, and information-based policy instruments) as well as the coherence of policies across different sectors and domains (e.g. water, agriculture, land use, urban planning, energy, and finance). An assessment of the structure and operation of the institutions that design, implement and evaluate policies and activities in the water sector is equally vital for ensuring accountable and efficiently functioning investment environment. Finally, adequate resources and capacities are needed for policies to be delivered and institutions to function as intended.
3.1.2. Policies and institutional settings define the conditions for water-related investment
A country’s public policy and institutional settings create a set of multi-layered conditions for water-related investments that can be complex for governments, service providers and investors alike to grasp and navigate. As outlined in Chapter 2, water-related investments have characteristics that challenge conventional approaches to public and private financing, including long payback periods and often complex risk-return profiles and project attributes. This reflects the fact that water policies and institutions are focused on ensuring access to water as a dynamic resource managed across jurisdictional boundaries and is essential for life. This demands sustainable management over decades-long time frames, and has strong interdependencies with other policy domains (e.g. agriculture, energy, urban planning) (OECD, 2016[8]). The inherent complexity of many water-related policy interventions has contributed to investors’ perception of water-related investments as more risky and generally less attractive than those in other sectors (Streeter, 2017[7]).
Strengthening the enabling environment for investment requires governments to recognise this diversity of potential projects and investors as well as the spectrum of diverse types of water-related investments and consider how adjustments to policies and institutions could help to facilitate the types of investments and investors that are most needed in their water sector.
3.1.3. Key components for improving the enabling environment
Table 3.1 summarises key elements of the enabling environment for investment, including policy frameworks and institutional arrangements related to water. In addition to the elements included in the table, financial policies, regulations and markets need to be conducive to providing long term, low cost capital to fund infrastructure investments (see discussion in the section on blended finance). These elements are discussed in more detail in the section below.
Table 3.1. Key elements of the enabling environment for investment
Component |
Examples of instruments, mechanisms or interventions |
Selected examples relevant to the water sector that can influence the investment environment |
---|---|---|
Policy settings |
Legal and regulatory policy instruments |
Legal status for water resources Legal recognition of the human right to water Clear legal status for WSS service providers Laws and regulations for managing water resources allocation (e.g. abstraction limits, enforcement mechanisms, entitlements to use water) Laws and regulations related to water quality standards (for drinking water, wastewater treatment, pollution loads in water bodies, etc.)> Laws governing infrastructure and services for e.g. drinking water supply, wastewater collection and treatment |
Economic policy instruments |
Tariffs for WSS services Targeted subsidies to address household affordability constraints in accessing WSS services Charges or taxes for water abstraction or pollution (Polluter Pays principle) Markets to trade for abstraction entitlements and pollution rights Payments for ecosystem services Insurance for water related risks (drought, flood protection) |
|
Information-based policy instruments |
Information systems (e.g. data collection, monitoring and early warning systems on water quality/quantity, service quality and efficiency, asset status, etc.)1 Public registers and information schemes (e.g. disclosure requirements on WSS service operations or service provider finances) Education and training programmes for WSS service providers Communication strategies and campaigns (e.g. for households, farmers) |
|
Mechanisms to facilitate policy coherence across domains/sectors |
Systems for tracking and monitoring shared policy objectives in a given sector (e.g. checklists, tracking finance for activities with multiple objectives) Policy mainstreaming processes (e.g. climate policy mainstreaming across sectors) Designating coherence objectives as part of central government processes (e.g. budgeting) Intra- and inter-governmental water policy co-ordination mechanisms |
|
Institutional arrangements and provisions |
Independent oversight |
Regulation of the WSS sector (e.g. WSS tariff-setting) by an independent economic authority |
Devolution or decentralisation reforms for service delivery |
Devolution of authority for WSS service delivery to municipal/local level Reconfiguration of service provision boundaries to consolidate service delivery at a defined scale |
|
Mechanisms for accountability to e.g. citizens, service users |
Public consultation and participation requirements for water tariff reforms WSS service user feedback and complaint mechanisms |
|
Mechanisms to improve services |
Performance incentive structures and monitoring for WSS service providers (economic regulation of service provision) |
|
Supporting resources and capacities |
Finance for policy implementation |
Resourcing for effective auditing and enforcement of water regulation (infringement proceedings, etc.) |
Capacity building measures |
Technical assistance, education and training to improve the technical, human resource and financial capabilities of WSS service providers |
Note: The examples in this table illustrate some relevant settings and conditions, but cannot provide a comprehensive or fully accurate depiction of the enabling environment across all countries. Governments combine various instruments and interventions to support and reinforce each other to meet policy objectives.
Source: Authors
Strengthening policy settings
Legal and regulatory instruments
Legal and regulatory policy instruments set the fundamental rules and parameters for a well-functioning water sector. Governments use them not only to establish their long-term water policy goals and plans, but also to ensure the accountability and cost-effectiveness of the activities and investments undertaken to achieve those goals. Relevant laws and regulations range from instruments that define water quality standards, allocation regimes, flood protection standards, to legal frameworks governing the design and implementation of and the delivery of WSS services.
A well-designed regulatory framework is particularly critical in the water sector because of water’s fundamental role in ensuring the well-being of people and ecosystems and the function of many economic sectors (OECD, 2009[9]). Given the monopolistic nature of the market for WSS services, a strong regulatory regime is important to ensure the cost-effectiveness and efficiency of policy measures, and to provide assurance to financiers which seek both predictability and transparency in the regulation and design of services (World Bank, 2017[6]). A regulatory regime is only strong if and when compliance is monitored and enforced.
The regulation of water pricing and charges such as WSS service tariffs offers an insight into the interplay between water laws, public and political expectations for water policy and services, and the sustainability of water sector financing. Considering that WSS are essential services, the public often has the expectations for keeping WSS tariffs low, with accompanying political pressure to regulate to keep tariffs low, sometimes also due to concerns about service affordability2. This can directly inhibit adequate cost recovery, which WSS service providers need to work towards to enable the delivery of reliable, sustainable services
Laws and regulations focused in other policy domains – such as those governing competition policy and financial markets – also influence the conditions for water-related investment. In low- and middle-income countries in particular, underdeveloped financial sectors and markets are a widely recognised challenge for increasing water-related investment, particularly from commercial investors (Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]). For example, some countries have legal restrictions in place that limit the scope for both potential borrowers and lenders to engage in new water-related investments and do not facilitate the water sector’s participation in markets. Further, some countries require banks to lend certain percentages of their portfolios to local infrastructure projects in defined areas, which may not encompass water sector priorities (World Bank, 2017[6]). Similarly, there may be rules in place that confine service providers to borrowing from government sources or prohibit them from issuing corporate bonds, or banks may only be permitted to invest a limited percentage of their capital in securities sold by service providers (World Bank, 2017[6]). In the case of improving catchment management via payments for ecosystem services, financial transfers to farmers can be restrained by regulations designed to promote fair competition and trade (e.g. WTO or EU law).
Economic and financial instruments
Governments use a variety of economic and financial policy instruments to influence the behaviour of individuals, communities and organisations to help achieve water policy goals. Such measures generally aim to account for the costs or benefits that different actors incur from using services or from polluting or abstracting water resources3. Examples include instruments such as WSS tariffs, taxes, charges and fiscal transfers (e.g. subsidies), along with mechanisms such as markets for trading water entitlements or pollution permits, and conditional and voluntary incentive schemes such as payments for ecosystem services.
Economic and financial measures not only provide important price signals of the value of water and provide incentives for water-wise decisions, but are also a vital means for providing revenue streams. In the case of WSS, service providers’ ability to generate revenue is derived from tariff levels and structures, bill collection and the associated incentives they create; typically, the WSS service providers should aim to achieve sustainable cost recovery, efficiency in the provision and use of water, and service affordability (World Bank, 2017[6]). In both emerging and developed markets, low WSS tariffs are the main constraint to sustainable cost recovery and reliable revenue streams for WSS service providers (World Bank, 2017[6]; Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]). Tariffs are often fixed at a level that is well below what is needed to recover the costs of operations and maintenance (O&M) ( (Leigland, Trémolet and Ikeda, 2016[10]) in (Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3])). Figure 3.1 illustrates that average annual water bills (for a representative household) remain relatively low, even in many higher income countries.
To attract investors’ interest, tariffs need to be set in a predictable and transparent way with the aim of covering O&M costs, the cost of debt service and a progressive share of capital expenditure (CAPEX) where feasible. A lack of sustainable cost recovery can leave commercial lenders hesitant to provide loans as they need an assured sufficient and constant operating surplus that can service the debt over the maturity period (Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]).
While water tariffs provide a stable revenue stream for water supply and sanitation investments, it is more challenging to quantify and monetise the benefits of other water-related investments, such as for flood protection or water resource management. Dedicated economic instruments are needed to help internalise externalities and to create revenue streams to capture the benefits of such investments. Further, combining water-related investments with objectives from other domains, such as agriculture, energy, tourism and urban planning can help to exploit synergies, creating opportunities to capture additional revenues and can unlock investment by applying an integrated approach across the value chain of water-related investment (OECD, 2019[1]; OECD-WCC, 2017[11]; OECD, 2018[12]). Examples include pollution taxes, which can provide funding for investments in water quality or wastewater treatment. Taxes on urban development in floodplains or impervious surfaces generate revenues for flood protection measures. Abstraction charges can fund water resource management interventions and can help cover some of the costs related to droughts or water scarcity. Reduced storm water fees for non-residential customers can encourage direct investment by private property owners and thus reduce the burden on public budgets. (OECD, 2020[13]; OECD-WCC, 2017[11]).4 However, highlighting opportunities for synergies should not overlook the reality that there will inevitably be trade-offs among policy objectives that must be addressed. Table 3.2. summarises selected examples which generate funding for various water security interventions. Box 3.1 discusses cost recovery for water in the agriculture sector.
Table 3.2. Selected policy instruments to generate revenue for water-related investments
Policy instrument |
Type of costs to recover |
---|---|
Pollution taxes |
Wastewater treatment costs, investments in water quality improvements |
Taxes on urban development in floodplains or impervious surfaces |
Flood protection costs |
Abstraction charges |
Water resource management and allocation, costs related to drought or water scarcity |
Reduced storm water fees for non-residential customers |
Encourages direct investment by private property owners, reduces burden on public budgets |
Charges or fees on resources recovered from wastewater treatment |
Revenue generated from energy or nutrient recovery from wastewater treatment |
Source: Authors, based on OECD (2020) Financing Water Supply, Sanitation and Flood Protection, Challenges in EU Member States and Policy Options and OECD-WCC (2017) Session 3. Converting economic benefits of water security investments into financial returns. Background paper for OECD-WWC-Netherlands Roundtable on Financing Water, 12-13 April 2017, Paris.
Box 3.1. Cost recovery for water in the agriculture sector
Like the WSS sector, the agriculture sector also faces challenges in recovering the costs of O&M and capital. Irrigating farmers generally do not cover the costs of the water they access. Only nine of 39 respondents to a recent survey of countries that adhere to the OECD Council Recommendation on Water indicated that they have full cost recovery in place for both capital and O&M costs for irrigation. In Germany, for example, operators bear the full costs of capital and O&M, and the federal states set different abstraction fees, some of which internalise a portion of the environment and resource costs. Under the EU Water Framework Directive, countries are required to ensure that the water prices charged reflect the full costs (e.g. operation and maintenance costs, capital costs, environmental and resource costs), although full recovery is not required and derogations are possible for less-favoured areas or on grounds of social welfare.
Most country adherents to the OECD Council Recommendation on Water only partially recover the costs of capital and/or O&M. A limited number of countries responding to the survey (Austria, Denmark, Finland, New Zealand, Sweden and the United Kingdom) indicated that they are covering a progressive proportion of the capital costs of infrastructure in addition to O&M costs.
Cost recovery is even less common for groundwater, though the situation differs from surface water as costs are often borne by users of individual wells.
Information-based instruments
Information-based policy instruments can help to achieve water policy goals and create strong conditions for investment in two vital ways: as standalone information systems and products (e.g. monitoring databases, communication campaigns) and as an input and support to other policy measures and investments (e.g. to inform water resource allocation reforms, or WSS tariff restructuring). Information systems (including accounting and measurement frameworks) are a key example of information-based instruments (such as for data collection, monitoring, and early warning systems on water resource quality/quantity; water-related risks; water infrastructure assets; WSS service efficiency, quality and quantity). Other examples include public registers and information schemes (e.g. disclosure requirements for WSS service operations or provider finances), education and training programmes (e.g. for WSS service providers or new investors), and communication strategies and campaigns (e.g. targeted at key audiences to facilitate or accompany other policy measures). Each of these play a role not only in ensuring access to salient information for decision makers, but also in creating a transparent and accountable water sector in which the public (including investors) can have confidence.
A prominent challenge is the lack of detailed knowledge in most countries of the current state of water infrastructure and assets across multiple water sub-sectors. For example, in the European Union, member states lack a detailed knowledge of the rate of asset renewal in the WSS sector (OECD, 2020[13]). Where the rate of renewal is known, it is usually below a level that would be consistent with assets’ life expectancy, which suggests an urgent need for increased renewal efforts to avoid the rapid decay of built infrastructure and declining service quality. The deterioration of assets also results in water leakage and reduced water quality, creating greater challenges for WSS service providers while affecting the health of humans and ecosystems and increasing downstream treatment costs (OECD, 2020[13]).
Countries face similar data challenges for flood protection: only a few countries monitor financial flows for this purpose, making it difficult to project further investment needs (OECD, 2020[13]). Limited knowledge and data on both the state of infrastructure and existing financial flows make it difficult to identify or monitor problems and properly plan improvements, and are thus a major barrier to investment. In some countries, ageing networks are expected to be the single biggest driver for investment in water supply and sanitation (OECD, 2020[13]).
Box 3.2. Information-based instruments for accurate knowledge of WSS assets
In recognition of the vital need for better access to robust water data (observations, processed data and model output), the international High Level Panel on Water (2016-18) endorsed the World Water Data Initiative. In its first phase the initiative resulted in the production of good practice guidelines for water data policy by the Australian Government and the World Meteorological Organization (WMO). The High Level Panel on Water recommended that the subsequent second phase, directed by the WMO, should inter alia support the dissemination of guidance for improving water data policy and secure funding for new innovations in water data (United Nations, 2018[16]).
A key area of innovation in information-based instruments for water management is in the use of artificial intelligence (AI), including for more accurate knowledge of WSS assets. A recent report estimates that AI-enabled innovation for the water sector will contribute USD 200 billion in value to the global economy by 2030 (Mehmood et al., 2020[17]). AI is already being used in countries such as Singapore, Kenya and the United States to support the predictive maintenance of water supply and wastewater assets and to track non-revenue water. These developments are occurring as part of a shift away from traditional scheduled inspection and maintenance approaches towards the use of intelligent sensor-physical systems that monitor the condition of assets (e.g. identifying leaks, blockages and damage) to inform the scheduling and prioritisation of maintenance. Machine learning algorithms are also being used to calculate the likelihood of failure of water infrastructure. Countries are also using AI to forecast water demand and consumption, monitor water reservoirs and dams, track water quality, and monitor and predict water-related disasters.
On the regulatory side, France has embarked on a programme that aims to contribute to better knowledge of the state of the assets for water services, thus supporting more accurate planning and decisions for operation, maintenance and renewal. A regulation issued in 2020 requires local authorities to inventory public networks for water supply and sanitation. An index was set to assess compliance with this requirement. When an authority scores below 40 (out of a maximum score of 120), the abstraction charge aid to the water agency is multiplied by two. There is no such incentive for sanitation. In 2014, two thirds of water services in France failed to comply with this regulation (figure provided by Canalisateurs de France, based on SISPEA data).
Sources: (OECD, 2020, p. 66[13]; Mehmood et al., 2020[17]; United Nations, 2018[16]; WMO, 2018[18])
Mechanisms to support policy coherence
As noted above, water’s essential role across many sectors means that governments should aim to continually assess and improve the coherence of water policies with those of related domains to ensure that priorities, measures and investments support, rather than undermine, one another. Some prominent examples of policy domains that intersect directly with water include agriculture, climate, energy, health, industry, urban planning and land use policy (OECD, 2016[8]). Common mechanisms for policy coherence include processes by which governments systematically assess how a given sector integrates other sectors’ objectives in its policies and measures (e.g. checklists for new policy proposals, finance tracking and monitoring, such as for water-related finance as a share of dedicated climate finance). Processes that centralise certain policy priorities in decision-making are another example (e.g. mainstreaming, central government budgeting). Effective cooperation both within and between governments and non-state actors – i.e. at horizontal and vertical scales – can enhance coherence among different institutions. Address potentially competing policy aims will require identifying and addressing trade-offs.
Improved policy coherence can help to ensure that water-related investment decisions are taken with a systems perspective and are not isolated from broader government decision making and priority setting. In the absence of such coherence efforts, water projects and investments can be left exposed to significant risk as a result of unforeseen or inadequately considered influences from other policy domains.
Strengthening institutional arrangements
Alongside the policy settings outlined above, the institutional arrangements that govern and facilitate the operation of a country’s water sector can have a considerable influence on the enabling conditions for water-related investment. It is important that the institutions that are part of the water policy landscape are designed and fully adapted according to each country’s specific context, governance systems and structures, and policy priorities, as underscored in the OECD Water Governance Principles (OECD, 2016[19]). Overall, investors are attracted to working with institutions that have established autonomy and leadership at the right levels to deliver on their mandates, offer confidence in their financial management capabilities, and are well equipped to help ensure transparency, accountability and predictability (World Bank, 2017[6]; Streeter, 2017[7]).
The devolution of authority for water sector functions – particularly decentralisation processes for local-level WSS service provision or water resources management at basin level – are a key example of institutional water sector reforms that aim to improve economies of scale and the conditions for investment. The devolution of WSS service delivery needs to be to the right level to ensure sufficient scale of operations, reduce operating costs, and support economic viability (Streeter, 2017[7]). In many countries, decentralisation processes are fragmented or incomplete. In emerging market countries in particular, municipal and local-level institutions often have weaker capacities and need significant support to improve their administration, planning and operations if they are to be deemed creditworthy (Streeter, 2017[7]). While decentralising service delivery can increase accountability by devolving responsibility to a level that is closer to the service user, it can also allow for greater variation in the design and enforcement of policies, make central oversight more onerous and complex, and introduce financial sustainability issues (World Bank, 2017[6]).
To address issues such as these in decentralisation processes, there are a number of options and imperatives. WSS service providers require clear mandates to support their financial self-sufficiency and autonomy. This requires sufficient capacity and independence to develop accurate projections on costs to inform tariff setting as well as long-term planning for infrastructure O&M and service delivery, with adequate consultation with connected authorities and the public (service users/customers), and without undue influence from political cycles and interests (Streeter, 2017[7]). Processes and mechanisms that support accountability and transparency in WSS service provision include requirements for systematic public consultation in decision making, as well as standardised, publicly available financial information and disclosure requirements for contractual processes (Streeter, 2017[7]).
Many countries opt to establish designated institutions with a mandate to independently oversee water sector operations, facilitating economic regulation and creating incentive structures to improve the performance of service providers. The independent regulation of public WSS service providers has been an increasingly common government response to deteriorating quality of WSS service delivery and, when well-designed, can help to reduce political interference in implementing key economic instruments such as tariffs (Mumssen, Saltiel and Kingdom, 2018[20]). Independent economic regulation can take various forms according to countries’ governance structures and priorities, and is examined in more detail below. While independent local- or national-level regulators can be instrumental in reducing political influence and financial mismanagement in service provision, they are not a silver bullet, and local circumstances should inform the appropriate solution that supports adequate oversight of service provision by a properly resourced and autonomous regulator (Pories, Fonseca and Delmon, 2019[3]).
Ensuring adequate resources and capacities to support policies and institutions
As noted in the above, two vital underlying components of a strong enabling environment for water-related investment are sufficient resourcing and capacities to enable policies to be implemented and institutions to function as intended. This reflects the principle that policy and institutional plans for the water sector should be backed by sustainable financing and resourcing strategies adapted to the specific context (OECD, 2020[13]). Naturally, adequate resourcing entails ensuring appropriate levels and structures of funding and financing are available to support policy implementation and institutional operations – for example, sufficient resources to carry out audits and enforce water regulations (and e.g. to undertake infringement proceedings when regulations are breached). These fundamental resources should be accompanied by efforts to ensure that institutions have appropriate levels and types of capacity and expertise. Stronger capacity is typically pursued through measures such as technical assistance, education and training aimed at improving the technical, human resource and financial capabilities of WSS service providers.
Water sector institutions need adequate capacities in order to attract investors, maximise existing finance, and increase their potential to attract, manage and sustain new and innovative investments into the future (Streeter, 2017[7]). In some cases, a commitment from institutions to undertake capacity improvement reforms may be a condition for receiving finance, as it will help to maximise the sustainability of that investment over the long term (Streeter, 2017[7]).
To improve the enabling conditions for investment, capacity building measures can target different types of institutions. For example, WSS service providers might receive technical assistance to reduce non-revenue water or improve billing and collection, and through this, improve their creditworthiness (OECD, 2019[1]). To increase local banks’ capacity to evaluate the profitability of water-related investments, financial providers might be provided with technical assistance and training to assess the financial viability of investments in the sector. Capacity building measures that are well designed and embedded in institutions over time can help to ensure that staff have the right skill sets and are motivated to achieve sector strategies and policies and participate in organisational change processes (World Bank, 2017[6]). This better positions them to meet minimum performance standards and supports staff to recognise incentives for improved performance (e.g. in service delivery, in financial management).
Capacity considerations such as these are vital for governments seeking to improve the conditions for investment and support investor confidence in local-level institutions. Ideally, local governments’ and WSS service providers’ capacities should be addressed as a pre-condition for introducing local borrowing (Streeter, 2017[7]). Investors seek evidence that providers have a strong ability to manage taxes and tariffs, collect revenues, prepare and manage transparent budgets, devise capital plans, co-ordinate contracts and tender processes, and conduct accountable consultation processes with the public and investment partners (Streeter, 2017[7]). Such capacities at the provider level are also important to enable national and sub-national governments and independent regulators to access the information they need to carry out their own responsibilities in determining and reforming water policy.
3.2. Make the best use of existing sources of finance and assets
Structural and operational inefficiencies limit the optimisation of available funding and existing assets in the water sector. The water sector has traditionally relied heavily on public finance (and concessional loans in developing countries), which in many cases has contributed to the inefficient allocation and use of existing funding. This section explores five options that governments can consider to focus their efforts to make better use of existing sources of finance and assets, and lay the groundwork for increasing access to more diverse sources of finance across the water sector. A focus on both the supply and demand side of finance provides two distinct entry points to address the financing challenge. Options to consider include:
improving timely asset management to reduce operational inefficiencies
sound capital expenditure planning
targeted allocation of public subsidies
seizing opportunities to improve economies of scale, and
creating and maintaining incentives for performance.
Action in these areas can generate efficiency gains and financial savings that can be used to provide better services and contribute to broader policy objectives (such as more secure, less polluted water resources and healthier ecosystems). WSS service providers and related institutions with transparent and efficient operations benefit not only from an increased and more reliable revenue base, but also from increased credibility that reinforces customers’ willingness to pay for quality services and encourages investor confidence. This helps to ensure a sustainable stream of finance to meet the full scope of a country’s service needs, address emerging challenges for the sector, and free up scarce public funds to be deployed to other policy priorities (World Bank and UNICEF, 2017[21]).
3.2.1. Improving timely asset management to reduce operational inefficiencies
Timely management of water assets – such as reservoirs, pipes and wastewater treatment facilities – supports efficient operations and maintenance (O&M) that in turn strengthens the sustainability of water services and supports water security (OECD, 2016[22]). When timely asset management is prioritised, asset owners and managers are able to identify and address O&M needs in the present – rather than deferring them to be borne by future water managers or service users – and ensure that deteriorating assets do not increase overall water-related investment needs. Timely asset management adequately accounts for assets’ economic life spans as well as the emerging challenges that the water sector will face over the coming decades. This involves a focus on sustaining assets throughout their full life cycles – from their design and construction to O&M and continuous monitoring and evaluation to facilitate necessary improvements in response to future risks (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]; World Bank, 2017[6]). As such, timely asset management can facilitate the supply of finance by ensuring cash flow reliability.
Conversely, insufficient investment in asset management reduces existing assets’ value and increases the risk that assets will need to be prematurely replaced. It can also mean that maintenance efforts are preoccupied with fixing asset breakdowns, rather than upgrades that have been strategically prioritised (ADB, 2013[24]). While this section focuses on the need for timely asset management, this issue is closely interlinked with the need for robust capital expenditure planning, which is examined in the next section.
As outlined above in Section 1 on the enabling environment for investment, a number of conditions are needed to support strong O&M – notably sustainable cost recovery based on an appropriate mix of revenue from the “3Ts” (tariffs, taxes and transfers) (OECD, 2009[25]). For WSS, low tariff levels are typically the primary factor preventing the recovery of O&M costs and thereby inhibiting adequate maintenance, reducing assets’ performance and shortening overall asset life (World Bank and UNICEF, 2017[21]). Where revenues from tariffs are insufficient to recover O&M costs, the gap needs to be filled using tax revenues that are carefully targeted, predictable and transparent to facilitate rigorous O&M (World Bank and UNICEF, 2017[21]).
Timely asset management is only possible when it is informed by accurate, sufficiently detailed data on the state and renewal rates of assets, yet as noted above, many countries lack this information (OECD, 2020[13]). A clear, well-articulated vision of asset renewal needs and accurate forecasts of water demand and risks allows WSS service providers and water management authorities to rigorously plan O&M and future investments (OECD, 2016[22]). This information can also support transparency about the effectiveness of services, and act as a basis for establishing precise, secure service contracts, reducing information asymmetries and rent-seeking behaviour (OECD, 2016[22]). Box 3.3 illustrates how various tools and technologies are being used to gather more precise data on assets and inform their sound management.
Box 3.3. Technologies and methodologies for data gathering and analysis to inform water asset management
Urban WSS service providers in developed countries have been increasingly relying on remote sensing and imaging technologies to acquire precise knowledge of assets’ status and performance levels, particularly those that are located underground (see, for example applications of AI discussed in Box 3.2). This information supports better planning of investments in maintenance and renewal to improve system reliability (e.g. to repair damaged pipes). Innovative and emerging tools and technologies expand the scale and scope of infrastructure monitoring, and extend the time horizon for asset management.
In New Zealand, the city of Auckland has used geographical information systems to overlay actions and investments that have a direct or indirect effect on freshwater quality, including those targeting storm water asset maintenance, renewal and development, cycleway and road construction, and network infrastructure development (e.g. broadband rollout).
In the United States, the Massachusetts Water Resources Authority developed a predictive maintenance strategy based on condition monitoring, and the probability and consequences of failure of each component. The programme increased equipment availability to 99%; it achieved cost savings by eliminating unneeded and low-value preventive maintenance work, and shifting the freed-up resources to predictive tasks and actual maintenance work. Predictive and probability-based maintenance illustrates a shift from zero-risk asset management (which translates into high degrees of infrastructure redundancy) to more thorough risk analysis, allowing more strategic and cost-effective asset management.
Sources: Adapted from (OECD, 2016[22]; OECD, 2015[26]; OECD, forthcoming[27])
Where the renewal rates of water assets are known, they often reflect a significant backlog of investment in O&M for existing assets. In the WSS sector in European Union countries, renewal rates are typically below levels that would be commensurate with assets’ life expectancy (OECD, 2020[13]). Other parts of the water sector – such as agricultural water – face similar challenges with ageing and deteriorating assets: for example, while Japan has invested heavily in its irrigation infrastructure over the last 50 years, more than 20% of the core irrigation facilities have now exceeded their expected lifespan (OECD, 2019[28]).
Failure to monitor assets, resolve problems or implement upgrades in a timely way can lead to excessive water losses, including non-revenue water, which undermines the efficiency and effectiveness of water services and raises costs. High rates of non-revenue water are often a sign of operational inefficiency and can provide a partial insight into the extent of backlogs of investment in O&M (OECD, 2020[13]). As non-revenue water can be driven by a combination of issues arising from key operational aspects of service provision – such as water production and distribution, asset maintenance, management of service users, and billing – timely asset management is just one of the possible solutions5 (Sy and Ahmed, 2016[29]). A recent OECD study found that there is significant potential to reduce non-revenue water in EU countries including Bulgaria, Poland, Cyprus6 and Romania, including through targeted maintenance of assets to improve leakage control and drive asset renewal and modernisation (OECD, 2020[13]). Such asset-focused interventions can be accompanied by measures such as performance based contracts to improve incentives for higher O&M performance, or capacity building programmes to build service providers’ skills in managing the technical dimensions of O&M. Indeed, in some cases, such measures can reduce or fully avoid the need for capital-intensive asset upgrades by minimising non-revenue water through other means (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]).Figure 3.2 illustrates the position of select countries with respect to the operating expenditure (OPEX) ratio (total annual operational revenue over total annual operating cost) and the share of non-revenue water (NRW). A higher OPEX ratio reflects a higher share of cost recovery for OPEX, providing more stable financing for timely maintenance of infrastructure assets. However, it is notably that there is significant scope for improvement to reduce non-revenue water, irrespective of the OPEX ratio.
3.2.2. Sound capital expenditure planning
CAPEX in the water sector should be carefully planned to ensure that finance is used to maximise economic, social and environmental benefits and improve overall capital efficiency. As noted in the above section, the need for well-planned, efficient CAPEX is interlinked with the need for investment in robust O&M; both are critical to making the best use of existing sources of finance and assets over their full life cycles (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]). This interconnection is illustrated by the WSS sector’s emphasis on the need to move away from the “design, build, neglect, rebuild” approach that has traditionally characterised capital expenditure in many countries and shift to a more cost-effective “design, build, maintain” model (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]). While the imperatives for operational efficiency have been gaining attention in the WSS sector, capital costs amount to around 50% of the total costs of service provision, which suggests that it is equally important to identify and exploit opportunities to reduce wasteful capital spending and make better use of existing finance and assets (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]).
Sound CAPEX planning should focus on reducing capital costs and minimising the associated long-term costs of O&M (World Bank and UNICEF, 2017[21]). This can be done in various ways. For example, planners should ensure that demand management options have been fully explored and new infrastructure is actually needed; policies are coherent across sectors, and exposure and vulnerability to water-related risks are considered; lower cost options have been considered in determining selected approach; robust design standards are in place; overpricing is mitigated (with costs and contract awards adequately regulated and monitored and transparently benchmarked); and communities are involved to provide local oversight (World Bank and UNICEF, 2017[21]). They should also conduct cost-benefit analyses with a view to supporting policy coherence and solutions that generate multiple benefits, including those that are difficult to monetise (such as nature-based solutions, potentially in combination with more traditional “grey” infrastructure) (see discussion on NbS in Section 3). Addressing trade-offs across geographic scales needs to be considered, though this can add significant complexity.
Investment in the water sector has traditionally focused on large-scale CAPEX, while commonly overlooking smaller investments that could improve performance or maximise local capacities and increase operational efficiency over the longer term. Planning that over-emphasises large-scale CAPEX can result in expensive yet underused infrastructure: a considerable share of WSS infrastructure, particularly in low- and middle-income countries, is oversized and fails to be used to capacity, or is not connected to sewerage networks at all (World Bank, 2017[6]). This sometimes occurs when technical standards are imported from high income countries and insufficiently adapted to the local context (World Bank, 2017[6]). Unnecessary costs can also arise in the design, selection and implementation of new infrastructure due to inefficient procurement processes, limited competition, or vested interests and biases towards the use of certain (and often more expensive) technologies (World Bank, 2017[6]). A lack of capacity and/or sufficient performance incentives for planners and operators can also drive poor CAPEX decisions. All of these issues not only undermine well-planned CAPEX, but also diminish the credibility and creditworthiness of service providers, limiting their ability to attract commercial finance (OECD, 2018[30]).
A bias in CAPEX planning towards large-scale “grey” and networked solutions can also impede the consideration and adoption of alternative options that may cost less now or in the future offer the same levels of service, often with other social and ecological benefits. This is an especially critical issue in countries that still have sizable populations lacking access to safe, reliable WSS services. Decentralised WSS systems can sometimes have lower costs and offer greater flexibility in hard-to-reach or rapidly changing environments (such as informal settlements), and avoid the need for large investments in piped infrastructure (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]). Experience in Dakar, Senegal, offers one example: a 2012 study found that the estimated annualised cost for sewerage services was almost USD 55, while the cost of on-site sanitation with faecal sludge management was estimated at less than USD 12 ( (Dodane et al., 2012[31]) in (World Bank, 2017[6])). These decentralised systems can deliver cost savings relative to conventional networked infrastructure, although should be accompanied by reliable monitoring and enforcement capacity.
Nature-based solutions (NbS) are another example of interventions with strong potential cost-benefit ratios. They are generally less capital-intensive ‑ with lower O&M and replacement costs, can avoid lock-in associated with capital-intensive grey infrastructure, and appreciate in value over time with the regeneration of ecosystems and their associated services (OECD, 2020[13]). NbS can also present distinctive challenges in terms of investment design, funding and financing (further details in the following section).
A disconnect between the accountability and incentive structures of asset financiers and asset operators can also undermine cost-efficient capital expenditure. This is particularly the case in low- and middle-income countries, where WSS service providers are often public entities that pay either nothing or a minimal cost for the infrastructure they use for service delivery (i.e. it is highly subsidised) (World Bank, 2017[6]; Kingdom et al., 2018[23]). This can directly constrain service providers’ accountability for asset use and management, and limit their incentives to pursue adequate cost recovery. Experience in some higher income countries, where the full cost of service delivery is accounted for, reflects that the debt service to repay loans for capital costs can be significant. For example, capital costs amount to an average of 49% of total costs for water utilities in England and Wales in the United Kingdom (Kingdom et al., 2018[23]).
3.2.3. Targeted allocation of public subsidies
Funding from public budgets is a significant source of funding of water services and water resources management. Yet in many countries the allocation of public funding could be better designed and allocated to improve equity and ensure the best use of available finance. Public subsidies refer to transfers that fill the gap that results from inadequate cost recovery through pricing. In the context of water supply and sanitation services, a subsidy7 occurs when a water user pays less for a product or service than the cost to the service provider, and the responsibility for covering the difference is shifted onto a third party, such as the government, other water users, or future generations (Andres et al., 2019[32]). Subsidies may be direct financial transfers from one entity to another (e.g. from a government to a service provider) or implicit transfers, such as non-payment for services or delayed maintenance (Andres et al., 2019[32]).
When well designed and deployed, public subsidies can be an important means for extending access to water resources and services for groups that may otherwise struggle to access them (e.g. due to affordability constraints), and need to be carefully targeted, transparent and predictable (World Bank, 2017[6]). Subsidies often fail to meet these criteria, instead distorting prices or creating perverse incentives that negatively affect water availability, quality or demand, including generating impacts beyond the water sector, for example through detrimental impacts on biodiversity via the intensification of agriculture. In such cases, governments should reform subsidies to ensure they meet their intended purpose, or phase them out where appropriate, using transition plans that avoid adverse impacts on vulnerable groups (OECD, 2016[8]).
This section focuses on examples of subsidies in the WSS and agricultural water sectors to identify some of the available options for fairer allocation that can support the best use of available resources. Table 3.3. outlines further examples of subsidies in the different parts of the water sector.
Table 3.3. Examples of subsidies in water services and water resources management
Transfer mechanism |
Example |
---|---|
Direct transfers of funds |
Capital investment subsidies for water supply and sanitation providers |
Foregone tax revenue |
Environmental pollution charges that do not cover the cost of pollution, as well as special reductions or exemptions |
Foregone user charge revenue |
Water supply and sanitation tariffs that do not cover the cost of service provision; lack of abstraction charges; reduced electricity tariffs for irrigation pumps |
Transfer of risk to government |
Government compensation to households and firms for property damage due to water‑related disasters |
Induced transfers |
Cross-subsidies for water supply and sanitation services (industrial vs. household tariffs) |
Economic advantage due to unequal regulation or policy |
Different regulations or charges for industry discharging pollutants to sewer systems or directly to water bodies |
Note: These are illustrative examples and not an exhaustive list of all subsidies that may exist in the water sector.
Sources: (OECD, forthcoming[27]) adapted from (EAP Task Force, 2013[33]).
Subsidies in the water supply and sanitation sector
Governments have traditionally heavily subsidised the WSS sector, usually with the overarching aim of expanding access to safe WSS services and capturing the positive externalities of access to WSS services (e.g. benefits for public health, productivity or educational outcomes). A recent study finds that subsidies are prevalent across countries, regardless of their region or income level (Andres et al., 2019[32]). This is not only because of the fundamental need for governments to support access to safe WSS services, but also because of the networked nature of many WSS services. Approximately 65% of the cost of supplying piped water and 80% of the cost of sewerage systems are for long-lived capital assets; this can allow service providers to use pricing structures in the short- to medium-term that do not cover capital or O&M costs, relying on subsidies that are often driven by pressure to keep prices low for users (Andres et al., 2019[32]).
Most existing WSS subsidies are costly, non-transparent and distortionary: they typically fail to benefit users through better services or lower prices, can allow rent-seeking by governments and service providers, and can limit service efficiency and sustainability (Andres et al., 2019[32]). They are also often poorly targeted and regressive. For example, subsidies commonly focus on networked services that poorer communities cannot access or afford, and ultimately disproportionately benefitting wealthier segments of the population that are already connected to services (see Box 3.4) (Andres et al., 2019[32]; Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34]).
Box 3.4. Potential limitations of WSS subsidies that are delivered through tariff mechanisms
Subsidies that are delivered through tariffs for WSS services tend to be poorly targeted and regressive, as the most common tariff structures are unable to effectively direct subsidies to poor households. Studies have shown that such subsidies in fact lead to more unequal distribution of resources as compared to if subsidies were equally distributed among the population, due to errors of inclusion as well as of exclusion from the subsidies (Fuente et al., 2016[35]).
In Lima, Peru, 20-30% of the population faces water affordability issues (the critical share of total water expenditure in income is set to 2%). As many as 90% of poor connected customers receive a WSS subsidy; however, 91% of the subsidy beneficiaries, or 78% of the connected population, are non-poor (Barde and Lehmann, 2014[36]). A similar situation is observed in Nairobi, Kenya, where households in the lowest wealth quintile receive 15% of the total WSS subsidies delivered.
Source: (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34])
Subsidies in the WSS sector need to be more carefully designed and targeted if they are to facilitate access to sustainable services and efficiently address equity and affordability issues. This means accurately identifying and aiming subsidies at priority groups (e.g. poor and vulnerable populations) and priority types of services (e.g. avoiding a disproportionate focus on urban, networked water services and duly addressing other areas of need, such as for rural sanitation services) (Andres et al., 2019[32]). Subsidies may target either connection fees (e.g. one-off financial support to expedite connection to existing or new networks, or the recurrent part of water bills (when there is one). Rather than being tied to individual expenditures, subsidies can also be made conditional on improved performance by service providers, using transparent key indicators and targets for better service results (Andres et al., 2019[32]).
Subsidies for WSS services tend to be most effective when they are decoupled from service access and consumption charges, and are instead provided as separate, targeted measures – for example, through dedicated funds for payment relief to poor households, or via rebates, vouchers or lump sum transfers to water users. Subsidies that are based on the volume of water consumed can distort consumption and, as a result, hamper efficient allocation of water resources ( (Reynaud et al., 2016[37]) and (OECD, 2011[38]) in (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34])). This implies that measures should be designed in order to secure basic needs, rather than be based on measured consumption at the household level. In Chile, policymakers have created a clear distinction between basic water needs and optimal consumption. Eligible poor households are provided with vouchers that help them cover a smaller or larger share (depending on their assessed needs) of the bill for basic water volumes, but never for volumes above this level. This guarantees that the social measures never cover water for profligate use (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34]).
Whether they are phasing out an existing subsidy or considering the introduction of a temporary one, governments should prepare well-considered “exit strategies” for subsidies’ eventual removal. These should be informed by whether the conditions driving the need for the subsidy are long-standing, permanent, or will change or disappear over time. Proposals to remove subsidies should be transparently consulted upon and communicated, with phase-outs accompanied by complementary measures such as legal reforms and transitional measures that account for the impacts of lost benefits (Andres et al., 2019[32]).
Subsidies for agricultural water
Governments often provide public subsidies for agricultural water; as is the case in the WSS sector. This can create perverse incentives and distortions that harm the efficiency, equity and/or sustainability of water resources management. One example is water-related input subsidies (e.g. of the costs of irrigation, fertilisers, pesticides or groundwater pumping): by lowering input costs, they can directly undermine water allocation regimes or harm water resources in certain contexts (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39]). Other examples include forms of support for agricultural activities that indirectly affect water resources, for example by encouraging the use of water, fertiliser, pesticides, or livestock intensification. Both types of subsidies can harm water resources by encouraging the overuse, overconsumption and/or pollution of surface water and groundwater (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39]).
Farm subsidies that negatively affect water resources are often designed with a different policy objective in mind – for example, they may effectively raise agricultural production or profitability, yet trigger inefficient or unsustainable water use or pollution of water resources (OECD, 2007[40]). When a subsidy has unintended negative consequences for water quality and quantity, it is sometimes highly politically sensitive or controversial to attribute the consequences to the subsidy, and this can be an early stumbling block for governments seeking to reform or remove it. For example, support for irrigation efficiency technologies might increase water consumption, to the detriment of other users and water ecosystems, due to a misrepresentation of the local hydrology or farmers’ response ( (Grafton et al., 2018[41]) in (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39])). Long-standing subsidies can sometimes be viewed by certain groups as entitlements.
Subsidies that negatively affect water resources can also further entrench existing inequalities. For instance, if the size of a subsidy is proportional to the amount of land owned, it will likely benefit wealthy farmers with larger farms. Subsidies’ impact on equity can also be indirect: irrigation subsidies can exacerbate existing operations and maintenance deficits by encouraging more water use, which in turn deteriorates the quality of the service and the availability of the resource (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39]). This can affect poor farmers the most, as they are often downstream users at the end of irrigation systems and cannot afford to invest in alternative sources of water or cope with the degradation of water quality (e.g. due to salinisation) (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39]).
As in the WSS sector, to improve equity and ensure that any agricultural water subsidies are fair and consistent with water policy objectives, governments can use packages of measures to reform the subsidies (e.g. through better targeting) or, as appropriate, phase them out over time. These measures can be combined to complement each other, and may include, for example (Gruère and Le Boëdec, 2019[39]):
pilots and demonstration projects that allow governments to test and make a case for the adjustment or removal of subsidies in certain locations before they are scaled up
legal or governance reforms that increase transparency around subsidies
engagement and consultation with key stakeholders to foster transparency and build trust in reform processes, and
purposefully designed and targeted transfer payments to certain groups, to protect or insulate them from short-term shocks or negative impacts from the reform.
To be effective, these actions typically require a lengthy but clearly time-bound implementation period, fortified by a continual effort to sustain political buy-in throughout the process of the reform.
Data and tools to improve the equity of water sector subsidies
The importance of access to accurate information and tailored methods for improving the fairness of water sector subsidies cannot be overstated. Governments should be attuned to how technological development and data innovation are creating new opportunities to better tailor and target subsidies.
For example, in the WSS sector, relevant data is indispensable to inform the tariff-setting process as well as the design of accompanying social measures, yet decision makers and service providers’ reform efforts can be hampered by data restrictions. For example, an absence of metering limits detailed documentation of water use, and in some countries, privacy laws prevent service providers from accessing data on the households “behind” the meters (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34]). However, when affordability and equity issues are addressed through separate measures outside of the water bill, relevant data – such as on household incomes and health – can be more readily available. The World Bank has piloted the use of remote sensing and street view data along with machine learning algorithms to map poor communities in Luanda, Angola, to inform the targeting of subsidies (Andres et al., 2019[32]). Analytical tools such as these can be instrumental in supporting governments to accurately identify which groups benefit or lose as a result of existing subsidies, as well as how subsidies may be better tailored to reach those groups as needed. Such analysis is fundamental to any rigorous effort to more fairly allocate subsidies in support of overall water policy objectives.
3.2.4. Seizing opportunities to improve economies of scale
Governments may consider institutional and market reforms to improve economies of scale, and through this, reduce operational costs and investment needs in the WSS sector. Aggregation reforms in the WSS sector are one option for reducing fragmentation in service delivery and optimising the use of existing sources of finance and assets.
As discussed above in Section 1 on the enabling environment for investment, the authority for WSS service provision in many countries is decentralised and devolved to the municipal or local level. While this is typically driven by the recognition that WSS services are intrinsically local and therefore best managed at that level, poorly designed or incomplete decentralisation can result in the creation of small, under-resourced WSS service provider institutions with inadequate capacities for administration and financial management, planning, and/or technical operations (Streeter, 2017[7]; OECD, 2010[42]). Decentralisation reforms can be particularly challenging for countries that need to provide WSS service coverage in areas with low density and/or hard-to-reach populations (e.g. rural areas, remote areas, or informal settlements). In such contexts, WSS services are often provided via devolved, dispersed networks of small providers that struggle to efficiently allocate their limited resources over large and sometimes technically complex service areas. This can create a varied and fragmented landscape for WSS service provision that is difficult to coherently oversee and sustainably finance.
To address these fragmentation challenges, some countries opt to adjust the scale and scope of WSS service provision by aggregating service provider institutions (OECD, 2010[42]). For example, aggregation reforms may seek to deliver WSS services at a more appropriate scale by creating a single institution that is responsible for services across multiple municipalities or within a given region. They may also adjust the scope of a provider’s responsibilities by either reducing or expanding the range of WSS services it delivers. Aggregation reforms generally aim to reduce perceived inefficiencies and low capacities in WSS service delivery by ensuring that providers have a customer base of appropriate size and a staff with the necessary capabilities to cost-effectively deliver WSS services (ERM, Stephen Myers and Hydroconseil, 2005[43]). This can in turn make WSS service providers financially viable, improving their creditworthiness and attractiveness to investors.
Currently, work is underway in Estonia and Lithuania on these issues, in the context of policy dialogues led by the OECD in co-operation with the European Commission DG Reform. The work will examine options for different modalities of water utilities sector consolidation, increasing social equity in access to - and prices for - WSS services in these countries. It will consider different scenarios of consolidation, including consolidation based on the principles of scale (national, regional, basin level) or/and scope (aggregation of such functions as technical maintenance, customer relation, revenue collection, etc.).
Aggregation reforms can have a variety of drivers and take different forms, depending on countries’ legal, regulatory and institutional frameworks. Like reforms of WSS tariffs or subsidies, aggregation processes can also be influenced by political cycles and interests, given their potential implications for different institutions’ roles and responsibilities, mandates and resources. Aggregation reforms might be locally-led and voluntary (e.g. arising from local governments’ initiative), incentivised and supported by a higher level of government and locally implemented, or wholly mandated and led by a higher level of government (ERM, Stephen Myers and Hydroconseil, 2005[43]). These drivers can be an important determinant of the willingness of existing service providers and other government institutions to support or participate in aggregation. For example, authorities at the local level may sometimes be reluctant to engage with aggregation reforms, due to concerns about losing their ability to oversee and adequately respond to customers’ demands and concerns, or losing access to and oversight of existing sources of finance, or where local utilities perform multiple functions. Factors such as these have delayed some countries’ reforms (OECD, 2020[13]). Governments also need to consider whether their aggregation process will be accompanied by a transfer of asset ownership to the level of service provision – this depends on the country context and identified service needs, and can be another sensitive factor (ERM, Stephen Myers and Hydroconseil, 2005[43]). Regardless of aggregation reforms’ main drivers, these considerations underscore the need for thorough scoping, consultation and negotiation processes for aggregation reforms among different levels of government and institutions.
Countries’ various experiences with aggregation to date reflect that while they require a strong grasp of institutional incentives and potentially extensive or lengthy negotiations, they can be most effective when they combined with complementary measures aimed at improving services (such as independent regulation or programmes to strengthen performance). Indeed, aggregation commonly leads to a need for governments to reform existing mechanisms for the oversight of service provision (ERM, Stephen Myers and Hydroconseil, 2005[43]). Aggregation of service providers can also be important in facilitating cross-subsidies between water users and territories, such as between rural and urban areas. This is the case in Romania and Bulgaria, and to a lesser extent in Lithuania, Latvia and Poland (OECD, 2020[13]).
3.2.5. Creating and maintaining incentives for performance
Strong administrative and operational performance within the institutions that manage water resources and deliver WSS services is vital to ensuring the best use of existing finance and assets. In the WSS sector, inadequate performance requirements and incentives for service provision can have various drivers – such as insufficient institutional accountability structures, a lack of well-defined and attainable performance standards, and/or insufficient institutional resources and capacities to enable good performance. Such conditions can translate to low motivation and poor standards for O&M, deteriorating assets, and low service quality. In turn, this reduces providers’ credibility and public trust in their ability to provide high quality WSS services – and can result in, for example, low user willingness to pay for local WSS services, or decisions by central government authorities to allocate much-needed finances to other purposes that are deemed more worthy or valuable. These issues also limit service providers’ creditworthiness and attractiveness to investors.
The section above on the enabling environment outlined the importance of policy and institutional settings – supported by the necessary resources and capacities – in creating the conditions for accountable, effective and efficient water service provision and ensuring reliable, financially sustainable institutions. Mechanisms for the independent regulation of services and information-based instruments are two types of measures that can help to make service providers’ performance transparent and set standards and incentives to further improve it. This section briefly expands on these measures and their role in driving higher performance to optimise existing finance and assets.
The role of independent economic regulation in driving consistent performance
Service accountability and transparency can be limited when the roles and responsibilities of the different actors involved in WSS services are not delineated and structured through clear institutional arrangements (e.g. for government authorities, asset owners, and service operators). Institutional structures sometimes also fail to provide clear requirements and incentives for service providers to improve service efficiency, meaning there is limited impetus for them to address problems or strengthen services in order to confront future challenges. Governments may struggle to require or incentivise higher service provider performance where the functions and powers of policy- and decision-making (e.g. on the design of economic instruments) are not explicitly separated from operations. Where such institutional separations do exist, regulatory bodies sometimes still lack the necessary powers to ensure that service provision complies with regulations and/or other standards.
Properly resourced independent regulation can help to address these issues, providing a clear accountability structure for institutions and a basis for setting and enforcing service performance standards. The three core elements of sound water regulation are to protect the environment (water resources and broader ecosystems), protect service users’ (customers’) interests, and protect the quality of services (e.g. for drinking water or wastewater management) (OECD, 2020[13]). Independent regulation can be designed and implemented in different forms according to countries’ specific governance contexts and needs. Regulation may be conducted by government; by contract (with regulation specified through legal instruments); by one or multiple independent regulators (e.g. with separations between decision-making, management and financing); or by outsourcing selected regulatory functions to third parties (i.e. external contractors that undertake tariff reviews or benchmarking) (OECD, 2020[13]).
The way in which a regulator acquires performance information and sets performance targets for service provision is important in bridging any gap between governments’ and customers’ expectations (OECD, 2020[13]). An outcome-based approach can help to ensure that service providers’ focus is not simply on easily measured outputs, but also accounts for longer-term aims for WSS services and the environment. A regulator should expect the service delivery body to monitor its services, the operational performance of its assets, and how it is planning for resilient systems operation in the face of shocks, such as drought, process failures or cyber-attacks. Just as governments need to ensure adequate resourcing for the regulator, the regulator should ensure the adequate funding of service provision institutions to enable them to efficiently and effectively meet service standards.
Transparency is crucial: defined standards and targets, and service providers’ performance against them, should be published and made available to customers (OECD, 2020[13]). Customers should also expect to be able to express their views on levels of service, priorities for investment and options for major infrastructure where this is proposed. The extent to which customers participate in the development of business plans can influence both their behaviour – and how much they value water and the service they receive – as well as that of the service provider.
Information-based instruments for improving performance
Producing and sharing reliable information on WSS service providers’ performance is an important means for establishing and assessing their creditworthiness and transparently identifying areas for improvement (OECD and ADB, 2019[44]). Box 3.5. summarises examples of performance indicators for WSS services. Benchmarking can be a critical tool for stimulating progress and convergence towards standards and good practices. A variety of tools and mechanisms exist, using robust data collection mechanisms and various indicators which can be tailored to the priorities in a particular country or basin. The International Benchmarking Network for Water and Sanitation Utilities (IBNet) is a global mechanism, and there are others at smaller geographical scales. Another international example is AquaRating – a standard for assessing water and wastewater systems. AquaRating evaluates utilities based on key performance indicators and the adoption of best practices grouped into eight areas that include different stages and processes in the value chain ( (IDB, 2018[45]) in (OECD and ADB, 2019[44])). It helps WSS service providers to accurately gauge their current status, identify opportunities for improvement, and take actions to meet international good practices. Through this, AquaRating can provide lenders with critical information on creditworthiness to enhance the commercial financial flow to the water sector (OECD and ADB, 2019[44]).
Benchmarking processes and tools such as these also underscore the need for additional complementary information-based instruments: education, training and communication materials and programmes that strengthen service providers’ capacity to perform. Where WSS service providers have low capacities, this often includes a lack of performance-based management knowledge and practices and adapted business processes that can guide them in planning for the medium- and long-term (OECD and ADB, 2019[44]). Well-designed capacity building interventions can ensure that service providers are able to thoroughly understand and act on performance standards and incentives.
Box 3.5. Examples of performance indicators for WSS services
Building on international good practices, performance indicators for WSS services can focus on the following items. The relevance and relative weight of indicators would reflect local conditions.
Technical performance indicators
Leakage performance and targets for reducing leakage and other unbilled losses, such as illegal connections
Mains bursts (as a proxy for distribution network condition)
Sewer collapses (as a proxy for sewer asset condition)
Number of wastewater pollution incidents, such as from too-frequent operation of combined sewer overflows, or major failures at wastewater treatment works
Unplanned outages (loss of supply because of bursts, contamination, etc.)
Compliance with existing regulation
Drinking water quality compliance (integrating with and reinforcing the role of the drinking water regulator, where this is separate)
Level of compliance with environmental permits and standards (integrating with and reinforcing the role of the environmental regulator, where this is separate); this can also be an indicator of the quality and state of assets for water supply and wastewater treatment
Customer experience
Reducing per capita consumption for households and demand in other sectors on mains supplies
Risk of demand restrictions in a drought
Customer experience: how well billing queries are dealt with, information about planned outages and supply interruptions
Source: (OECD, 2020, pp. 99-100[13])
3.3. Optimise future investment needs by planning, setting priorities and sequencing investment
While financiers typically focus on the availability of a pipeline of bankable projects, government authorities and project developers should also situate these pipelines within broader strategic investment pathways to ensure they are resilient and contribute to water security and sustainable growth over the long term and preferably at the least cost. A long-term strategic approach can ensure that assets deliver anticipated benefits over their operational lifetime and avoid premature obsolescence or costly retro-fitting in the future. Such an approach would also help to secure a stable flow of investment opportunities and returns for investors.
Water-related investments need to be resilient to cope with systemic changes. A hallmark of resilience is the recognition that disruption of system functions will occur, sometimes due to expected events and other times due to unexpected ones, and thus, there is a need to plan for how to recover from them. Investment possibilities include efforts to increase system modularity, redundancy, flexibility, cohesion, adaptability, to name a few system characteristics that have emerged from ongoing research (Linkov et al., 2019[46]).
Recognising that the future is uncertain, governments can combine long-term strategic infrastructure perspectives with iterative decision making that can be adjusted over time as more information becomes available.8 This includes taking steps in the design, operation and financing of systems to avoid inefficient path dependencies or costly infrastructure retrofits, and consider how short-term actions potentially enable or foreclose future options. Governments can signal their intention and financial ability to tender water projects over a multi-year time span. This could also include governments fostering the development of commercial finance and capital markets able to lend at an affordable cost and appropriate long term maturity to water related projects. A focus on actions that promote additional flexibility, and provide opportunities to shift among options depending on evolving trends (economic, climatic, demographic, technological, etc.) are valuable in the context of uncertainty (OECD, 2018[47]). This includes consideration of nature-based solutions, which have significant potential to lower the costs of achieving water security and related co-benefits (e.g. for biodiversity, etc.) now and in the future.
In addition to taking a long-term view, strategic investment pathways should be designed at the relevant spatial scale. Individual water projects may be bankable, but could still undermine the management of water resources. For example, a narrow focus on investments in water use efficiency for particular users may or may not improve the overall sustainable management of the resource, potentially undermining other benefits. Strategic planning can also open up the potential to exploit interdependencies among related investments, for example, where certain investments can unlock opportunities for others. A case illustration of this approach can be found in the example of the Zambezi Basin (OECD, 2020[5]). While the benefits of such pathways are better understood, operational challenges remain, that relate to the need to coordinate and align several projects, institutions and stakeholders, over a potentially long timeframe. Planning and coordination raise transaction costs. Institutional arrangements are required to address them (e.g. intermediaries and dedicated financing mechanisms).
Policy coherence is especially important for “landscape approaches”, which are an increasingly common framework for creating integrated projects that pursue multiple policy goals within a given landscape. Landscape approaches recognise that the landscapes in which water management occurs are not static but instead continually adapt and evolve under the influence of interconnected social, ecological, economic and political dynamics (Cardascia, 2019[48]). By engaging different actors and mobilising capital at the scale of the landscape, these approaches can serve as pool mechanisms to channel investments with multiple objectives in different water sub-sectors. They can appeal to institutional investors such as pension funds and insurance companies by facilitating the issuance of local currency bonds in the capital markets of the countries in which those investors are already established and operating (Cardascia, 2019[48]).
3.3.1. Nature-based solutions to deliver multiple benefits in the context of a changing climate
The international community is increasingly exploring nature-based solutions (NbS) in response to deliver water security, especially in the context of a changing climate. NbS are measures that protect, sustainably manage or restore nature, with the goal of maintaining or enhancing ecosystem services to address a variety of social, environmental and economic challenges (OECD, 2020[49]; OECD, 2021[50]). The measures can include improved management practices, such as reduced fertiliser or pesticide use in agriculture, or investments reforestation or building artificial wetlands (Trémolet, S. et al., 2019[51]). NbS can also play a role as a complement to conventional “grey” infrastructure, in the form of hybrid solutions, increasing the effectiveness and operable life of infrastructure. For instance, integrating NbS into grey flood control measures can increase water absorption capacity, reduce velocity and regulate peak flows (Browder et al., 2019[52]). Wetlands can contribute to carbon sequestration, having the potential to store twice the amount of carbon as the world’s forests (UNEP, 2019[53]). NbS offer new opportunities to address a number of water security risks in a cost-effective and integrated way.
More systematic consideration of NbS in strategic investment planning can deliver multiple benefits
NbS are multifunctional and have hence the potential to deliver co-benefits and to address several water security challenges simultaneously. For instance, wetlands can enhance water quality and mitigate flood and erosion risk (Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]). Further, the use of NbS can maximise the synergies between ecosystem health, biodiversity and human well-being and increasing climate change mitigation as well as adaptation and resilience. NbS are adaptive systems, making them conducive to managing uncertainty related to climate change by avoiding or delaying lock-in to capital intensive grey infrastructure, allowing for flexibility to adapt to changing circumstances (OECD, 2020[49]; Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]; OECD, 2013[55]). For example, a floodplain may attenuate larger volumes than can be held within a levee lined river channel, also delivering co-benefits of sustaining bird and fish species and providing recreational benefits to people (World Bank, 2017[56]).
The benefits of NbS have been found to outweigh the costs of implementation and maintenance in a range of contexts. NbS can result in substantial avoided costs. For example, investing in watershed restoration and conservation could save water utilities across the world’s largest cities an estimated USD 890 million annually (Kapos et al., 2019[57]). Additionally, NbS can deliver multiple co-benefits with significant economic value, translating into a strong investment case. In Europe, for example, it was found that the restoration of rivers yielded an estimated net societal economic benefit of an estimated EUR 1 400 per hectare annually compared to unrestored rivers, in addition to increasing flood protection, enhanced agricultural production, carbon sequestration and recreation (Vermaat et al., 2015[58]).
In some cases, NbS can be more cost-effective than grey alternatives, particularly for less extreme hazards. For example, NbS were estimated to be 2-5 times more cost-effective than grey infrastructure across 52 coastal defence projects in the US, and most effective to defend against waves up to half a metre high and at increased water depths (Narayan et al., 2016[59]). Finally, investments in NbS have the potential to stimulate the economy by creating jobs. For example, in the EU, the restoration of 15% of degraded ecosystems, consistent with the EU 2020 Biodiversity Strategy, is estimated to result in between 20 000 and 70 000 full time jobs (OECD, 2019[60]). The potential for investing to receive multiple benefits rather than traditional single-purpose investments could become essential in the context of reduced public and overseas development aid budgets (Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]).
Distinctive features of NbS create challenges for scaling up and financing
Despite opportunities and expected resilience dividends from NbS, their uptake remains limited and projects are often launched on a pilot basis and in an ad hoc way. The distinct characteristics of NbS create barriers for readily scaling up NbS. As summarised in (Dominique et al., 2021[61]) such features include difficulties in quantifying and monetizing benefits and long time lags between investment and the realisation of benefits. High transaction costs arise due to the specificity of ecosystem and climate dynamics, as well as multiple parties engaged in such projects. Other NbS-specific features that inhibit up-scaling are their large spatial scales that can cross multiple jurisdictions, limits to standardisation and barriers to funding and financing. Further, existing institutional, regulatory and financial processes are typically designed to support the development and financing of grey infrastructures, which can create a mismatch between an enabling environment that would be conducive to NbS and the status quo (Dominique et al., 2021[61]; OECD, 2020[49]; Trémolet, S. et al., 2019[51]; OECD, 2021[50]).
Monetising diffuse and non-market benefits is difficult and comparable metrics for NbS performance are lacking. This can bring a number of problems with the risk-return profile of NbS projects, deterring possible funders and financiers. Further, availability of robust performance data is limited, data may be collected inconsistently or incompletely at different times and different spatial scales. A lack of common metrics and the fact that NbS are generally unique and site-specific interventions make it challenging to compare measures and to assess the risks. (OECD, 2020[49]; Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]; Trémolet, S. et al., 2019[51]; OECD, 2021[50]) In the absence of robust performance data for NbS, authorities charged with managing risks to communities or investors often default to better known and tested solutions (Dadson et al., 2017[62]).
Decision-making and planning processes are usually geared towards grey infrastructure and can inadvertently discourage the use of NbS. Traditional economic or financial appraisal tools, such as cost-benefit analysis (CBA) do not necessarily capture the value or full range of benefits and co-benefits from NbS projects (Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]). Multi-criteria analysis provides a means to account for a broader range of market and non-market benefits. Various agencies are often not set up to provide the level of coordination among various partners, jurisdictions and landowners needed for NbS as they tend to operate in sectoral silos and thus favour single-purpose grey infrastructure. Further, the benefits from NbS may take longer timeframes to develop and can change over time. This might entail varying benefit-cost ratios over time, which could appear unfavourable compared to grey infrastructure during the planning and prioritisation phase (Trémolet et al., 2021[63]). A lack of short-term benefits could deter investors operating over short return periods. Moreover, investors often evaluate projects over the lifetime of the financing vehicle rather than the operational lifetime of the projects, which limits access to finance for NbS. (OECD, 2020[49]; Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]).
Options for scaling up NbS and their financing
In order to increase their uptake, NbS need to be considered on an equal footing with grey infrastructure. Thus, decision-making processes around planning, implementing, operating and financing infrastructure need to be adapted through regulatory and legislation changes and the development of new appraisal tools (Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]; OECD, 2020[49]). Beyond a focus on pilot projects and dedicated programmes, NbS would benefit from explicit inclusion in strategic policy and planning processes and documents, such as National Water Strategies, National Adaptation Plans, National Determined Contributions related to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change, National Biodiversity Strategies, among others (Dominique et al., 2021[61]).
A more conducive enabling environment can be supported by shifting from an output-based approach focused on building infrastructure to an outcome-based approach focused on delivering services, such as water flow regulation, flood prevention and control, water quality improvement and so on. This promotes a shift from a focus from delivering infrastructure (typically conventional grey infrastructure) to delivering services, widening the range of possible solutions that can do so in a cost-effective way. For example, an economic regulator can promote specific service quality targets through the use of performance indicators while allowing utilities the flexibility to reach those targets in the most cost-efficient manner (Dominique et al., 2021[61]).
Expanding the traditional understanding of what constitutes an “asset” in the realm of water management would help to more broadly legitimize the use of NbS to deliver water services and expand their uptake (Cassin, Gunn and Matthews, 2021[64]). This requires ensuring that the regulatory, legislative and policy context recognise the services that NbS can deliver, and allowing for their use in the course of delivering regulated public services. The role of water sector regulators is especially crucial here. For example, when SABESP in São Paulo, Brazil, one of the leading water and sewage service providers in Latin America, faced a crisis of water shortage during the historic drought of 2014-15, it had to drastically re-adjust investment planning to strengthen the system’s resilience. The regulator’s role in allowing for the inclusion of these investments to increase resilience in the regulated asset base was decisive (OECD, 2019[65]).
Methods are needed which can evaluate and mainstream CBA for multi-purpose infrastructure, by adjusting discount rates as appropriate and evaluating projects over their operational lifetime rather than over their finance period. Projects in Bulgaria and Romania to implement flood risk management measures and have applied a broader range of appraisal tools, including multi-criteria analysis to better assess NbS compared with traditional approaches (OECD, 2021[66]). France, as another example, has launched a national programme to support the quantification and monetisation of the value of ecosystems and ecosystem services in 2012. The programme’s 2018 report estimates that the value of the capacity of French rivers to retain nitrogen exceeds EUR 2 billion annually. However, no monetary value could be attributed to nearly half of the ecosystem services analysed due to a lack of available data or appropriate methodologies (EFESE, 2018[67]).
Improving the evidence base to quantify benefits and the performance of NbS can provide a more robust basis for funding and financing. Some well-established initiatives have made important strides in quantifying benefits related to NbS. For example, the Water Fund in Quito Ecuador (FONAG) has promoted catchment protection for 20 years. It devotes significant effort to monitoring the impact of the interventions. Impact monitoring entails the quantification of benefits in terms of water quality and quantity, with feedback on the design of the portfolio, and as an input for return-on-investment studies. These efforts are fundamental to promoting trust in the Fund and sustaining financial contributions that support its operations (De Bièvre and Coronel, 2022[68]).
Dedicated funding arrangement and financial incentives can scale up the use of NbS and have already been used in a number of countries (Trémolet et al., 2021[63]). In Peru, the Sanitation Sector Law requires utilities to use 1% of their collected tariffs to support NbS for water quality (Cooper and Matthews, 2020[54]). Further, governments can offer direct financial support for pilot projects and technical capacity building, such as seen in the United Kingdom, Canada, the United States and the European Union. In Europe, the EU Horizon 2020 programme has allocated approximately EUR 185 million to research and pilot the applications of NbS between 2014 and 2020 (OECD, 2020[49]). New project finance models that fit the characteristics of NbS’ cash profiles need to emerge. Box 3.6 describes how the clustered approach has been used for water-related investments in hybrid infrastructure in Semarang in Indonesia.
Box 3.6. Clustered investment pathways for hybrid water infrastructure in Semarang
The city of Semarang in Indonesia is facing multiple interconnected water-related challenges. Climate change and urbanisation are increasing the city’s exposure and vulnerability to flooding. In order to address not only the impacts but also the causes of these water-related risks, the city has identified several reinforcing interrelations between population growth and urban expansion, infiltration rates, frequency and risks of flooding, tax income, deterioration of maintenance levels of water infrastructure and declining groundwater resources.
To tackle the challenge holistically, the city has created five clusters of projects, aiming at starting a new dynamic between water security and economic growth. The five clusters considered are: micro-interventions; spongy mountain; rechannelling the city; feeding the industry; and recharging the aquifer. The implementation of several hybrid projects will proceed in phases, starting in 2020 with approximately one measure per cluster at small scale in order to a) create the evidence base, b) generate participation of communities, public and private sectors and c) build capacity of authorities to procure projects successfully and the private sector to deliver projects.
The Implementation Strategy aims at improving the bankability of each concept by enabling multi-sectoral investments and by making use of blended finance strategies. Different sources of finance will be mobilised such as Official Development Aid (ODA) targeting relevant SDGs, climate finance, municipality local revenue sources and efficiency gains driven by private sector participation. If investors are aware of the synergies embodied by the clusters, access to finance could become conditional upon successful implementation of previous projects within the clusters. Hence, strategic investment pathways comprised of phased hybrid infrastructure clusters could contribute to closing the implementation gap of water security strategies.
Source: (Altamirano, 2019[69])
References
[24] ADB (2013), Water utility asset management: A guide for development practitioners, Asian Development Bank, https://www.adb.org/documents/water-utility-asset-management-guide-development-practitioners.
[69] Altamirano, M. (2019), Hybrid (green-gray) water security strategies: a blended finance approach for implementation at scale, Background Paper for the Roundtabe on Financing Water, 26-27 November, Manila, https://www.oecd.org/water/Session3b.Hybrid_(green-gray)_water_security_strategies.pdf.
[32] Andres, L. et al. (2019), Doing More with Less Smarter Subsidies for Water Supply and Sanitation, The World Bank Group, http://www.worldbank.org/gwsp.
[36] Barde, J. and P. Lehmann (2014), “Distributional effects of water tariff reforms – An empirical study for Lima, Peru”, Water Resources and Economics, Vol. 6, pp. 30-57, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wre.2014.05.003.
[52] Browder, G. et al. (2019), Integrating Green and Gray, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/31430.
[48] Cardascia, S. (2019), Financing Water Infrastructure and Landscape Approaches in Asia and the Pacific, Background paper Session 4, 5th Roundtable Meeting on Financing Water, 26-27 November, https://www.oecd.org/water/Session4.Financing_Water_Infrastructure_and_Landscape_Approaches_in_Asia_and_the_Pacific%20.pdf.
[61] Cassin, J. (ed.) (2021), Why Governments Embrace Nature-based Solutions: The Policy Rationale, Elsevier.
[64] Cassin, J., E. Gunn and J. Matthews (2021), Nature-Based Solutions and Water Security.
[63] Cassins, J., E. Lopez Gunn and J. Matthews (eds.) (2021), Chapter 15. Funding and Financing to Scale Nature-based Solutions for Water Security, Elsevier.
[54] Cooper, R. and J. Matthews (2020), Water finance and Nature-based solutions, K4D.
[62] Dadson, S. et al. (2017), “A restatement of the natural science evidence concerning catchment-based ‘natural’ flood management in the UK”, Royal Society, https://doi.org/10.1098/rspa.2016.0706.
[68] De Bièvre, B. and L. Coronel (2022), “Investing in catchment protection: The Water Fund model”, in Investing in Water and Growth.
[31] Dodane, P. et al. (2012), “Capital and Operating Costs of Full-Scale Fecal Sludge Management and Wastewater Treatment Systems in Dakar, Senegal”, Environmental Science & Technology, Vol. 46/7, pp. 3705-3711, https://doi.org/10.1021/es2045234.
[33] EAP Task Force (2013), Improving the Use of Economic Instruments for Water Resource Management in Kyrgyzstan: The Case of Lake Issyk-Kul Basin, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/env/outreach/2013_Kyrgyz%20report%20on%20Eis%20for%20WRM%20Eng%20Web.pdf.
[67] EFESE (2018), Les milieux humides et aquatiques continentaux, Ministère de la transition écologiques et solidaire, https://www.ecologie.gouv.fr/sites/default/files/Th%C3%A9ma%20-%20Les%20milieux%20humides%20et%20aquatiques%20continentaux.pdf.
[43] ERM, Stephen Myers and Hydroconseil (2005), Models of Aggregation for Water and Sanitation Provision, https://ppp.worldbank.org/public-private-partnership/library/models-aggregation-water-and-sanitation-provision.
[35] Fuente, D. et al. (2016), “Water and sanitation service delivery, pricing, and the poor: An empirical estimate of subsidy incidence in Nairobi, Kenya”, Water Resources Research, Vol. 52/6, pp. 4845-4862, https://doi.org/10.1002/2015wr018375.
[41] Grafton, R. et al. (2018), “The paradox of irrigation efficiency”, Science, Vol. 361/6404, pp. 748-750, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aat9314.
[39] Gruère, G. and H. Le Boëdec (2019), “Navigating pathways to reform water policies in agriculture”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 128, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/906cea2b-en.
[15] Gruère, G., M. Shigemitsu and S. Crawford (2020), “Agriculture and water policy changes: Stocktaking and alignment with OECD and G20 recommendations”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 144, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/f35e64af-en.
[70] Haasnoot, M. et al. (2013), “Dynamic adaptive policy pathways: A method for crafting robust decisions for a deeply uncertain world”, Global Environmental Change, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2012.12.006.
[71] Haasnoot, M. et al. (2019), “Investments under non-stationarity: economic evaluation of adaptation pathways”, Climatic Change, pp. 1-13, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-019-02409-6.
[45] IDB (2018), AquaRating: an international standard for assessing water and wastewater, https://publications.iadb.org/publications/english/document/Aquarating-An-International-Standard-for-Assessing-Water-and-Wastewater-Services.pdf.
[57] Kapos, V. et al. (2019), The Role of the Natural Environment in Adaptation, https://cdn.gca.org/assets/2019-12/RoleofNaturalEnvironmentinAdaptation_V2.pdf.
[23] Kingdom, B. et al. (2018), Better Use of Capital to Deliver Sustainable Water Supply and Sanitation Services, World Bank, Washington, DC, https://doi.org/10.1596/30870.
[34] Leflaive, X. and M. Hjort (2020), “Addressing the social consequences of tariffs for water supply and sanitation”, OECD Environment Working Papers, No. 166, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/afede7d6-en.
[10] Leigland, J., S. Trémolet and J. Ikeda (2016), Achieving Universal Access to Water and Sanitation by 2030: The Role of Blended Finance, World Bank, Washington D.C., https://documents.worldbank.org/en/publication/documents-reports/documentdetail/978521472029369304/achieving-universal-access-to-water-and-sanitation-by-2030-the-role-of-blended-finance.
[46] Linkov, I. et al. (2019), The business case for resilience in water infrastructure investments, https://doi.org/10.1080/02626667.2018.1426858.
[17] Mehmood, H. et al. (2020), Strategic Foresight to Applications of Artificial Intelligence to Achieve Water-related Sustainable Development Goals, United Nations University Institute for Water, Environment and Health, Hamilton, Canada, https://inweh.unu.edu/wp-content/uploads/2020/04/Strategic-Foresight-to-Applications-of-Artificial-Intelligence-to-Achieve-Water-related-Sustainable-Development-Goals.pdf.
[2] Money, A. (2017), Scaling-up financing through an attractive risk-return profile, https://www.oecd.org/environment/resources/RT-Financing-Water-background-paper-session-A-Money-Oxford.pdf (accessed on 2 June 2020).
[20] Mumssen, Y., G. Saltiel and B. Kingdom (2018), Aligning Institutions and Incentives for Sustainable Water Supply and Sanitation Services: Report of the Water Supply and Sanitation Global Solutions Group, World Bank, https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/29795/126016-WP-P159124-PUBLIC-7-5-2018-12-14-46-W.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y.
[59] Narayan, S. et al. (2016), “The Effectiveness, Costs and Coastal Protection Benefits of Natural and Nature-Based Defences”, PLOS ONE, http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0154735.
[50] OECD (2021), Scaling up Nature-based Solutions to Tackle Water-related Climate Risks: Insights from Mexico and the United Kingdom, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/736638c8-en.
[66] OECD (2021), Sixth Roundtable on Financing Water: Discussion Highlights, Regional meeting: Europe, 7-8 December 2020, https://www.oecd.org/water/6th-Roundtable-on-Financing-Water-in-Europe-Summary-and-Highlights.pdf.
[14] OECD (2021), Toolkit for Water Policies and Governance: Converging Towards the OECD Council Recommendation on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/ed1a7936-en.
[13] OECD (2020), Financing Water Supply, Sanitation and Flood Protection: Challenges in EU Member States and Policy Options, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/6893cdac-en.
[49] OECD (2020), “Nature-based solutions for adapting to water-related climate risks”, OECD Environment Policy Papers, No. 21, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/2257873d-en.
[5] OECD (2020), Strategic Investment Pathways: The Zambezi Basin case study, https://www.oecd.org/water/OECD-(2020)-Strategic-investment-pathways-Zambezi-case-study.pdf.
[4] OECD (2019), A Typology of Water-related Investments.
[60] OECD (2019), Biodiversity: Finance and the Economic and Business Case for Action, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/a3147942-en.
[65] OECD (2019), Fourth meeting of the Roundtable on Financing Water, Regional Meeting Americas, 26-27 June, Washington DC, Discussion Highlights, http://www.oecd.org/water/Summary-RTmeeting-26and27June.pdf (accessed on 2 June 2020).
[28] OECD (2019), Innovation, Agricultural Productivity and Sustainability in Japan, OECD Food and Agricultural Reviews, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/92b8dff7-en.
[1] OECD (2019), Making Blended Finance Work for Water and Sanitation: Unlocking Commercial Finance for SDG 6, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5efc8950-en.
[12] OECD (2018), Blended finance for water-related investments, Background paper Session 1. 3rd Roundtable Meeting on Financing Water, 12 November, https://www.oecd.org/water/Background-Paper-3rd-Roundtable-Financing-Water-Blended-Finance-for-water-related-investments.pdf.
[47] OECD (2018), Developing Robust Project Pipelines for Low-Carbon Infrastructure, Green Finance and Investment, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264307827-en.
[30] OECD (2018), Third meeting of the Roundtable on Financing Water, 12 November, Paris Summary and Discussion Highlights, http://www.oecd.org/water/roundtable-financing-water-2018-summary-and-highlights.pdf (accessed on 2 June 2020).
[8] OECD (2016), OECD Council Recommendation on Water, https://www.oecd.org/environment/resources/Council-Recommendation-on-water.pdf.
[19] OECD (2016), OECD Council Recommendation on Water.
[22] OECD (2016), Water, Growth and Finance, https://www.oecd.org/environment/resources/Water-Growth-and-Finance-policy-perspectives.pdf.
[26] OECD (2015), Water and Cities: Ensuring Sustainable Futures, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264230149-en.
[74] OECD (2013), Scaling-up Finance Mechanisms for Biodiversity, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264193833-en.
[55] OECD (2013), Water and Climate Change Adaptation: Policies to Navigate Uncharted Waters.
[72] OECD (2012), A Framework for Financing Water Resources Management, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264179820-en.
[38] OECD (2011), Economic Instruments for Water Management, Working Party on Biodiversity, Water and Ecosystems.
[42] OECD (2010), Innovative Financing Mechanisms for the Water Sector, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264083660-en.
[25] OECD (2009), Managing Water for All, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/environment/managing-water-for-all_9789264059498-en.
[9] OECD (2009), Private Sector Participation in Water Infrastructure: OECD Checklist for Public Action, OECD Studies on Water, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264059221-en.
[40] OECD (2007), Subsidy Reform and Sustainable Development: Political Economy Aspects, OECD Sustainable Development Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264019379-en.
[27] OECD (forthcoming), Report on the implementation of the OECD Recommendation on Water.
[44] OECD and ADB (2019), Supporting the Mobilisation of Commercial Finance: Managing risk, improving performance and creditworthiness, Background paper Session 5. 5th Roundtable meeting on financing Water, 26-27 November, Manila, https://www.oecd.org/water/Session5.Supporting_the_mobilisation_of_commercial_finance.pdf.
[11] OECD-WCC (2017), Converting economic benefits of water security investments into financial returns, Backround paper Session 3. OECD-WWC-Netherlands Roundtable on Financing Water, 12-13 April 2017, Paris, https://www.oecd.org/environment/resources/RT-Financing-Water-background-paper-session-3.pdf.
[3] Pories, L., C. Fonseca and V. Delmon (2019), Mobilising Finance for WASH: getting the foundation right, Water.org, IRC and The World Bank, http://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/725521553154723194/pdf/Mobilising-Finance-for-WASH-Getting-the-Foundation-Right.pdf.
[73] PPIAF (2020), Non-revenue Water, https://ppiaf.org/sectors/non-revenue-water.
[37] Reynaud, A. et al. (2016), Review on International Best Practices on Charges for Water Management, Toulouse School of Economics.
[7] Streeter, W. (2017), Financing Water and Sewer Infrastructure in the Developing World, Taylor & Francis.
[29] Sy, J. and S. Ahmed (2016), “In the market for good practices on performance-based contracts for non-revenue water management”, World Bank Blogs, https://blogs.worldbank.org/ppps/market-good-practices-performance-based-contracts-non-revenue-water-management (accessed on 2 November 2020).
[51] Trémolet, S. et al. (2019), Investing in Nature for Europe Water Security, The Nature Conservancy, Ecologic Institute and ICLEI. London.
[53] UNEP (2019), Peatlands store twice as much carbon as all the world’s forests, https://www.unep.org/news-and-stories/story/peatlands-store-twice-much-carbon-all-worlds-forests (accessed on 24 March 2021).
[16] United Nations (2018), World Water Data Initiative - Summary, Sustainable Development Goals Knowledge Platform, https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/content/documents/hlpwater/12-WorldWaterData.pdf.
[58] Vermaat, J. et al. (2015), Assessing the societal benefits of river restoration using the ecosystem services approach, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10750-015-2482-z.
[18] WMO (2018), WMO steps up action on water, https://public.wmo.int/en/media/press-release/wmo-steps-action-water (accessed on 16 November 2020).
[6] World Bank (2017), Easing the transition to commercial finance for sustainable water and sanitation, http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/182521503466225465/pdf/119048-WP-REPLACEMENT-PUBLIC.pdf.
[56] World Bank (2017), Implementing nature-based flood protection: Principles and implementation guidance, http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/739421509427698706/pdf/120735-REVISED-PUBLIC-Brochure-Implementing-nature-based-flood-protection-web.pdf.
[21] World Bank and UNICEF (2017), Sanitation and Water for All: Priority Actions for Sector Financing, https://www.oecd.org/environment/resources/Session%204%20Sanitation%20and%20water%20for%20all%20-%20priority%20actions%20for%20financing.pdf.
Notes
← 1. Relevant data include: the state of water resources (quantity and quality), now and in the future, quality of water supply and sanitation services, exposure and vulnerability to water-related risks.
← 2. A recent re-examination of the issue of the affordability of WSS services finds that affordability measures are best delivered through targeted social measures, rather than through the water bill (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34]). The most appropriate responses vary according to national and local contexts, and usually combine: a capacity to target households most in need of support; low transaction costs, use of existing data and social programmes; and synergies with water conservation measures. Different tariff structures and levels have differentiated social impacts. See (Leflaive and Hjort, 2020[34]).
← 3. For more detail, see e.g. (OECD, 2012[72]); (OECD, 2016[8]).
← 4. Securing the revenue streams from these policy instruments for specific purposes requires earmarking. While the earmarking of revenues from environmentally related taxes (e.g. to fund spending on pesticide reduction policies) promote transparency and help garner public support and thereby the political acceptability of the tax, it also bypasses or pre-empts the annual budgets, where departments compete for funds on an equal footing, and creates a precedent for other government agencies to have their own earmarked funds (OECD, 2013[74]).
← 5. Non-revenue water can result from physical losses (due to e.g. poor asset quality and/or O&M, lack of leakage control), commercial losses (due to e.g. illegal connections and water theft, under-use of customer water meters, data and monitoring errors) and losses for authorised purposes that are not billed (e.g. for firefighting or certain consumer groups) (PPIAF, 2020[73]). Non-revenue water can be addressed through a range of interventions targeted at the multiple drivers of losses.
← 6. Note by Turkey: The information in this document with reference to “Cyprus” relates to the southern part of the Island. There is no single authority representing both Turkish and Greek Cypriot people on the Island. Turkey recognises the Turkish Republic of Northern Cyprus (TRNC). Until a lasting and equitable solution is found within the context of the United Nations, Turkey shall preserve its position concerning the “Cyprus issue”. Note by all the European Union Member States of the OECD and the European Union The Republic of Cyprus is recognised by all members of the United Nations with the exception of Turkey. The information in this document relates to the area under the effective control of the Government of the Republic of Cyprus.
← 7. More broadly, “water-harmful subsidies” may include the provision of water, power and other relevant services (piped water supply; irrigation water from the public network; drainage of land via collector drainage networks, etc.) at below their real cost (including exemptions and reductions for some users). They also include absolving economic agents from the full charge for their impacts on the water-environment, in terms of water quality or quantity (EAP Task Force, 2013[33]).
← 8. See for example, the approach of dynamic adaptive policy pathways (Haasnoot et al., 2013[70]) and the application of this approach to investments under non-stationarity (Haasnoot et al., 2019[71]).