A strong revival in exports is boosting growth
Strong economic performance and low inequality foster well-being
Environmental achievements and ambitions are high
Structural vulnerabilities remain in the financial sector
Public finances are under pressure from an ageing population
Reforms to the tax system would enhance growth
Work incentives need to be strengthened, while maintaining strong social protection
Finding direction for benefit reform
Reform priorities within the current system
OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2018
Assessment and recommendations
Abstract
A strong revival in exports is boosting growth
After a long period of lacklustre economic performance, robust growth has resumed. The Finnish economy suffered a series of sizeable adverse shocks alongside the global financial and economic crisis, facing major difficulties in the electronic and forest industries, in addition to a severe recession in Russia (OECD, 2012, 2014, 2016a). Sound fundamentals and policy settings helped weather the impact of those shocks and by early 2017 the economy had regained strong momentum, with recovering exports joining private consumption and investment as engines of growth (Figure 1). Domestic demand has expanded since 2015, as households have dipped into their savings to smooth consumption and invest in real estate. Investment in machinery and equipment picked up, as new industrial projects emerged and spare capacity began shrinking. Investment in R&D now also seems to be turning around after six years of decline, which bodes well for future productivity growth. The recovery is broad-based across economic sectors and high business and consumer confidence point to a strong expansion.
Nevertheless, Finland faces challenges. GDP per capita, while exceeding the OECD average, is significantly lower than in Denmark, Germany and Sweden, reflecting differences both in productivity and labour utilisation (Figure 2Figure 3). In Denmark and Norway, labour utilisation is relatively low despite high employment rates, due to the relatively few hours worked per person employed. A rapidly ageing population reduces labour supply and puts pressure on public finances. Hence, future growth and well-being will hinge on a higher employment rate and productivity gains, both in the private and public sectors.
The government has been implementing structural reforms across a wider range and with more determination and coherence than in most other OECD countries. It is pushing forward an ambitious and comprehensive programme aimed at enhancing competitiveness and boosting the growth potential of the economy, while ensuring the long-term sustainability of public finances. The Competitiveness Pact signed by the social partners in 2016 lowers unit labour costs by about 4% from 2017 (Box 1). The new wage negotiation model, agreed in principle as part of the Competitiveness Pact, implies a move from national-level collective agreements, extended by law to cover around 90% of workers, towards a system where sector-level collective agreements are coordinated following the lead of export industries. Such a system of “organised decentralisation” can contribute to constructive labour relations and flexibility at the different bargaining levels on wages and non-wage factors, such as working-time arrangements. Sectoral agreements concluded so far have been in line with the example set by exporting industries and are expected to slightly improve price competitiveness. Coordination hence seems to work despite the failure of social partners to reach a more detailed formal agreement on a Finnish wage bargaining model. The government programme also includes savings on government expenditure and a social welfare and health care reform aiming at reducing costs and enhancing equality in access to services, to be implemented from 2020 (Box 2).
Box 1. The Competitiveness Pact
The Competitiveness Pact, a tripartite labour market agreement signed in June 2016, aims at improving companies’ price competitiveness, increasing exports and employment and boosting economic growth. It is estimated to have lowered unit labour costs by about 4% from 2017, reversing a sizeable share of the competitiveness loss relative to Finland’s main trading partners over the preceding decade. Continued wage moderation and structural reforms pushing up productivity are expected to close the remaining gap over the next few years.
The cost reduction was achieved through the following measures:
Employees work 24 hours more per year for the same pay.
Public sector holiday bonuses are cut by 30% in 2017-19.
Employer social security contributions are permanently reduced and partly shifted to employees. The reduction amounts to about one percentage point in 2017-19 and minimum 0.58 percentage points after 2020.
Wages were frozen in 2017.
The Competitiveness pact is expected to increase employment by around 40 000 persons in the long run (Ministry of Finance, 2016).
The reduction in employees’ purchasing power implied by the Competitiveness Pact is broadly offset by cuts in income taxes targeted at low and middle income earners.
The reductions in labour costs reduce general government operating expenditure, but in the short run this is more than offset by the revenue lost from the tax and social insurance contribution cuts. Overall, the Competitiveness Pact and concomitant tax measures increase the budget deficit by about half a percentage point of GDP in 2017-19. However, as effects on economic growth and employment will gradually raise government revenue, the long-term fiscal impact is expected to be broadly neutral.
Box 2. The health, social services and regional government reform
The government has initiated an ambitious reform, which from January 2020 will shift the responsibility for organising health care and social services from municipalities to 18 newly created autonomous counties. The reform will change the structure, services and funding of publicly funded health and social services to increase customer focus, modernise services and improve the sustainability of general government finances. The aim is to provide people with services on a more equal basis, level out differences in health and well-being and curb cost increases. In addition, basic health and social services will be strengthened, individuals will have more freedom of choice and information technology will be used more effectively across the services. The reform will bring the sub-national government structure closer to that of the other Nordic countries, even though substantial organisational differences across these countries will remain.
The regions will be managed by elected councils, the first elections taking place in October 2018. As a result of the reforms, the 18 new counties will not only take over the responsibility for organising publicly funded health and social care, but also for rescue services, environmental healthcare, regional development, promotion of business enterprise, regional planning and steering, as well as promotion of the identity and culture of the counties. In addition, the counties will be responsible for other statutory regional services, including regional economic development and employment services. To support and facilitate cooperation between the counties, five collaborative catchment areas will be established to coordinate provision of services.
Financing for the counties will come entirely from the central government, imposing a strict budget constraint on counties. Funding will depend on needs, notably related to the age structure of the region’s population, and will be reviewed annually. A financial evaluation procedure will encourage sound financial management and allow making timely adjustments measures whenever necessary.
The reform is welcome, as the Finnish health system, while generally providing high quality services, suffers from inefficiencies, in particular inequalities in access to health care and excessive reliance on specialised relative to primary care (OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2012). Currently over 190 local organisations carry the responsibility for organising publicly funded health and social care. This results in fragmentation of service provision, hindering economies of scale and scope, and difficulties in organising services and recruiting qualified personnel.
A key challenge to improve the efficiency of the health care system will be to encourage competition between providers in a way which encourages innovation, with careful monitoring of the quality of care and enhanced dissemination of information and benchmarking of providers to facilitate user choice. Capitation-based compensation of primary care providers will help contain costs. The emphasis on prevention will be reinforced.
The success of the reform is crucial to meet the needs of an ageing population and ensure long-term fiscal sustainability. The government assumes that the reform will yield EUR 3 billion of savings annually, i.e. about 1.3% of 2017 GDP (Ministry of Finance, 2017a). This corresponds to a reduction in annual healthcare and social welfare real spending growth from 2.4% to 0.9% between 2020 and 2029. Achieving such cost containment seems feasible, but remains challenging. In particular, implementation costs of the new regional structures are uncertain, notably due to learning and recruitment challenges.
Key challenges are to increase the employment rate and to boost productivity. The government has set an ambitious target of 72% for the employment rate of the population aged 15-64 by 2019. Based on the OECD long-term growth framework (Guillemette et al., 2017) and assuming additional employees have average productivity, raising the employment to 72% would increase GDP per capita by about 1.5%. Reaching the employment rate of Sweden, which approached 77% in late 2017, would lift GDP per capita by 4.8%. Besides the Competitiveness Pact and measures to support business development and entrepreneurship, a better functioning labour market is needed to increase employment. The duration of unemployment benefits was reduced in 2017 by 100 days to 400 days for those with at least three years of work history, and to 300 days for those with a shorter work history, with the aim of strengthening work incentives. However, many unemployed workers will see only small net income increases, and some will even incur a loss upon return to work. The complexity of the benefit system is another obstacle to stepping into employment, particularly when responding to temporary job offers. A universal basic income, which is being experimented on a small scale, is sometimes presented as a solution. However, even though a basic income might enhance work incentives, its generalisation may increase poverty (from 11.4% to 14.1% in the scenario described below), and would require increasing income taxation by nearly 30% (OECD, 2017a). Hence, alternative routes to reform with the aim to simplify and coordinate working-age benefits to improve work incentives and adapt to a changing world of work need to be considered, taking into account the trade-offs they imply in terms of work incentives, distributional effects and fiscal costs.
Against this background, the key messages of this Survey are:
Policy settings need to continue supporting a balanced recovery, in terms of competitiveness, financial stability, public finances and environmental sustainability.
Reforms to the tax system would enhance support for growth.
Raising the employment rate is essential for growth and long-term fiscal sustainability. Work incentives need to be strengthened, while maintaining strong protection for the most vulnerable.
Economic growth is expected to edge down after the strong 2017 rebound, but to remain healthy. Exports and investment will remain strong, while private consumption will be held back by stagnating real income, as inflation picks up (Table 1). As employment growth has been sluggish until very recently and labour force participation has risen, the unemployment rate has declined only slowly (Figure 4). Nevertheless, continued robust GDP growth is expected to reduce unemployment over the coming years.
Table 1. Macroeconomic indicators and projections
2015 |
2016 |
2017 |
2018 |
2019 |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|
GDP |
0.0 |
1.9 |
3.1 |
2.5 |
2.0 |
Private consumption |
1.7 |
1.8 |
2.6 |
2.3 |
1.3 |
Government consumption |
0.0 |
1.2 |
-0.0 |
-0.3 |
1.0 |
Gross fixed capital formation |
0.7 |
7.2 |
7.8 |
3.5 |
3.5 |
Housing |
2.0 |
10.5 |
8.2 |
4.6 |
2.0 |
Business |
2.3 |
6.6 |
10.0 |
3.5 |
5.0 |
Government |
-5.2 |
3.9 |
1.0 |
2.0 |
0.9 |
Final domestic demand |
0.1 |
2.8 |
3.1 |
2.0 |
1.7 |
Stockbuilding1 |
0.2 |
-0.2 |
-0.7 |
-0.1 |
0.0 |
Total domestic demand |
1.2 |
2.6 |
2.4 |
1.9 |
1.7 |
Exports of goods and services |
0.8 |
1.3 |
8.3 |
5.5 |
5.0 |
Imports of goods and services |
3.2 |
4.4 |
2.5 |
4.4 |
4.3 |
Net exports1 |
-0.9 |
-1.2 |
2.0 |
0.4 |
0.3 |
Other indicators (per cent growth rates, unless specified) |
|||||
Potential GDP |
0.6 |
0.6 |
0.8 |
0.9 |
1.0 |
Output gap2 |
-5.1 |
-3.9 |
-1.7 |
-0.2 |
0.7 |
Employment |
-0.4 |
0.4 |
0.7 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
Unemployment rate3 |
9.4 |
8.8 |
8.7 |
8.4 |
8.0 |
GDP deflator |
2.0 |
0.9 |
0.9 |
1.0 |
1.5 |
CPI |
-0.2 |
0.4 |
1.0 |
1.7 |
2.0 |
Core inflation |
0.8 |
1.1 |
0.7 |
1.4 |
2.0 |
Household saving ratio, net4 |
-1.0 |
-2.5 |
-2.8 |
-2.7 |
-2.8 |
Trade balance5 |
-0.5 |
-1.2 |
-0.3 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
Current account balance5 |
-1.0 |
-1.4 |
-0.4 |
-0.6 |
-0.6 |
General government financial balance5 |
-2.7 |
-1.7 |
-1.1 |
-1.1 |
-1.1 |
Underlying government net lending2 |
0.6 |
0.6 |
-0.1 |
-0.9 |
-1.6 |
Underlying government primary balance2 |
0.8 |
0.8 |
0.1 |
-0.8 |
-1.5 |
Gross government debt (Maastricht)5 |
63.6 |
63.1 |
62.5 |
62.2 |
61.9 |
General government net debt5 |
-53.1 |
-53.4 |
-50.2 |
-47.5 |
-44.7 |
Three-month money market rate, average |
0.0 |
-0.3 |
-0.3 |
-0.3 |
-0.3 |
Ten-year government bond yield, average |
0.7 |
0.4 |
0.6 |
0.8 |
1.0 |
1. Contribution to changes in real GDP.
2. As a percentage of potential GDP.
3. As a percentage of labour force.
4. As a percentage of household disposable income.
5. As a percentage of GDP.
Source: OECD, Economic Outlook Database (EO 102).
The main risk for the Finnish economy is a slowdown in global growth, in a context where world trade prospects are clouded by policy uncertainty and geo-political risks. This would reduce demand for exports and weigh on income and investment. Finnish exports are particularly sensitive to demand for machinery and equipment, forest products, chemicals and metals (Figure 5, Panel A). Finland is mostly exposed to Europe, even though exports to Asia are also significant and growing rapidly (Panel B). Low probability events could hurt the economy (Table 2). On the contrary, a stronger-than-expected pick up in global investment would boost Finnish exports, as would a solid rebound of economic activity in Russia. The impact of competitiveness gains on exports could be stronger than foreseen. Domestic risks are limited. High indebtedness among some households could lower private consumption in the case of a rise in interest rates or a marked slowdown in income growth. On the upside, high consumer and business confidence may foreshadow stronger-than-projected private consumption and investment.
In the long term, steady growth and improvements in living standards hinge on productivity gains. Finland has an exceptional track record in education and innovation, which translated into strong productivity growth from the 1990s to the mid-2000s. However, multifactor productivity has stagnated since then, despite a recent rebound. This is partly due to cyclical factors and the global slowdown in productivity growth (OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016; OECD, 2015a), but Finland has lagged behind competitors over recent years (Figure 6). Educational performance, as measured by PISA and national surveys, has declined, but the government is currently upgrading comprehensive education, notably through enhancing learning environments, teacher competences and digitalisation, reforming vocational upper secondary education, and accelerating transitions to working life (Prime Minister’s Office, 2017). The ongoing reform to reduce the fragmentation of higher education needs to be completed to create more centres of excellence in teaching and research. Notwithstanding a recent pick-up, total investment in R&D is now below 3% of GDP compared to close to 3.5% before the 2007 crisis – largely because of a large drop in Nokia and the electronics industry more generally. Business subsidies largely support established industry and firm structures, especially in traditional sectors, rather than promoting innovation (Maliranta et al., 2016). But important productivity-enhancing structural reforms are being implemented to boost productivity, including an easing of retail trade and transport regulations, which will further alleviate product market regulations which are already fairly light on average.
Measures are also being taken to foster entrepreneurship, including from 2018 the merger of institutions promoting innovation, exports and investment into Business Finland, a one-stop-shop which will facilitate the creation of network projects responding to business needs and contribute to financing them. There is scope to reinforce cooperation between large firms, SMEs and public institutions, in particular with the aim of strengthening SMEs’ access to research and ability to expand on foreign markets, which is crucial to foster growth and economic diversity (OECD, 2017b).
Table 2. Possible shocks and their economic impact
Vulnerability |
Possible outcome |
---|---|
Protectionist measures affecting world trade growth. |
As Finland is very dependent on foreign trade, mounting protectionism would threaten growth. |
Geopolitical tensions |
Geopolitical tensions could hamper trade and investment. |
Global or regional financial crisis contagion. |
The Finnish financial system is dominated by Nordic banks with low liquidity buffers. A liquidity crisis triggered by events outside Finland could lead to difficulties in the banking sector, falling asset prices and a credit squeeze. |
Table 3. Past recommendations on productivity-enhancing reform
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Streamline regulations in retail trade, transport and construction. |
Land-use planning restrictions applying to large retail units have been eased. Rail passenger transport will be open to competition in the early 2020s and a new Act on Transport Services will facilitate interactions between different transport modes. |
Use funding criteria for higher-education institutions or R&D vouchers, to reinforce co-operation between companies, particularly start-ups, and universities. |
As of 2018, Business Finland will facilitate the creation of network projects responding to business needs and contribute to financing them. |
Strong economic performance and low inequality foster well-being
Finns enjoy one of the highest levels of well-being in the OECD, performing among the top 20% in education and skills, environmental quality, personal security, subjective well-being and social connections (Figure 7). However, average household net adjusted disposable income per capita is slightly lower than the OECD average, partly reflecting sluggish growth over the past decade, even though high taxes, which help finance high-quality free social services, also play a role. Civic engagement and governance is only slightly above the OECD average, due to relatively low voter turnout in recent elections. Health status is lagging behind the other Nordics, pointing to the need for reforming the health care system, not only to ensure financial sustainability, but also to improve health outcomes, in particular reducing health inequality. The employment rate of the population aged 15-64 is three percentage points above the OECD average, but more than four percentage points lower than in all other Nordic countries. This highlights the importance of the government objective of lifting the employment rate. Work and life balance, while much better than in the average OECD country, is not as good as in the other Nordics.
Income inequality remains low by OECD standards (Figure 8, Panel A). The Gini coefficient of income before taxes and transfers increased sharply in the early 1990s, mainly as a result of a large fall in employment during the deep recession which followed a financial crisis and the collapse of the Soviet Union (Panel B). The increase in market income inequality was initially offset by redistribution, but later in the 1990s lower taxes on capital income and reduced social benefits pushed up the Gini coefficient of income after taxes and transfers. Since the early 2000s, income inequality has remained broadly stable.
Gender inequality is very low in Finland, which comes second in the World Economic Forum Global Gender Gap Index 2016, behind Iceland and ahead of Norway and Sweden. The employment gap between men and women aged 15-64 is the second lowest in the OECD (Figure 9, Panel A). Women are well represented among top politicians, on the board of companies and among entrepreneurs, even though parity is not achieved. However, the gender pay gap is wide, partly because of strong gender specialisation across professions, with women being under-represented in well-paid activities like engineering and over-represented in public sector jobs, notably in health care and education (Panel B). Differences in fields of activity and jobs explain about half of the pay gap (National Institute for Health and Welfare, 2017). Young women are also more often in fixed-term employment than their male counterparts and tend to take long parental leaves, which weakens their career prospects. The combined duration of parental leave and home care allowance is among the longest in the OECD. The amount of the allowance is relatively low, but in combination with top-ups provided by some municipalities and childcare costs it can reduce incentives to work considerably (Panel C) (OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016).
Table 4. Past recommendations to promote gender equality
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Reduce the combined duration of parental leave and the homecare allowance to encourage female labour market participation. |
No action taken. |
Environmental achievements and ambitions are high
Overall energy intensity in Finland is significantly higher than the OECD average, in part because of the cold climate, the low population density and a relatively large share of energy-intensive industries (Figure 10, Panel A). A high share of renewables, especially the biomass by-products of the forestry sector, and the contribution of nuclear power keep average emissions per unit of energy relatively low, so that the economy’s carbon intensity is in line with the OECD average, and falling (Panel B). The four nuclear power stations currently supply nearly 30% of total electricity; a fifth station is under construction and a planned sixth station, replacing CO2-intensive coal, would bring that share to 60%. Finland is the first country in the world to license and start building a final repository for highly radioactive nuclear waste, with storage planned to begin from 2023 (Gibney, 2015).
Overall air quality is among the best in the OECD and unlike nearly all other countries, good air quality is nearly uniform across the country (Panel C). Water quality is also generally good and all urban areas are well-served by sewage treatment; some rural areas have little or no collective treatment, but where population density is very low the pollution and health risks are likely minimal. Some surface waters and coastal areas do suffer from excessive nutrients, largely due to run-off from agriculture.
Per capita waste generation in Finland is just below the OECD average (Panel D). The share going to recycling is somewhat above the OECD average, while heavy use is made of incineration, whose share has grown six-fold over the past decade, increasingly with energy recovery in either district heating systems or electricity generation. The rise in the landfill tax from EUR 15 per tonne in 2001 to EUR 70 per tonne since 2016 has, along with regulatory changes, encouraged this switch from landfill to incineration.
Revenues from environmental taxation are somewhat above the OECD median, with relatively high taxation of vehicles like in other Nordic countries. As elsewhere, environmental taxation on non-energy items, other than vehicles, is negligible in terms of revenue (Panel E). The tax system, along with other instruments like the EU Emissions Trading System (ETS), regulations and R&D, has a key role to play in achieving Finland’s ambitious climate change and environmental policy objectives. However, tax rates vary across energy uses – e.g. heating and process use, power production or transport – and sectors – e.g. energy producers, manufacturing industry or households. A number of industries or fuels benefit from reduced tax rates (OECD, 2013) or direct refunds. A few years ago, a working group led by the Ministry of Finance identified between EUR 2.7 and EUR 4.5 billion in production-linked reduced rates and direct subsidies which can heighten environmental pressures, mainly in energy, transport and agriculture (Hyyrynen, 2013). Although some of the environmentally harmful subsidies have been reduced since then, most remain, including in particular subsidies to energy-intensive industries, lower taxation of diesel compared to gasoline, low taxes on peat, agricultural direct and indirect (e.g. on fuel use) subsidies and the over-allocation of EU Emission Trading System (ETS) permits (Bragadóttir et al., 2014).
Diesel prices should be at least aligned with those of gasoline, but some compensatory measures may be required in the short term to preserve the competitiveness of the transport sector, including public transport. The transition should be gradual to allow users of diesel to adjust (Harding, 2014). Increasing taxes on peat should be considered, taking into account how substitution of imported fuels for peat would affect combined heat and power production and energy security, as well as activity and employment in some regions. Reforming agricultural subsidies is even more challenging, as a significant part of the sector may not survive without subsidies. Supporting some activities may be justified on social, cultural, territorial planning, strategic or food security grounds. Furthermore, agricultural subsidies are influenced by EU policies, notably the Common Agricultural Policy, so altering them requires coordinated action with other member states.
Finnish patenting activity has been much higher than the OECD average, when adjusted for population size, in recent years, with some tendency for activity to be focused more on environment-related patents than elsewhere (Panel F).
Table 5. Past recommendations on environmental sustainability
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
To reduce greenhouse gas emissions further, phase out environmentally harmful subsidies and better align the tax rate on emissions across sectors. |
Some energy, CO2 and vehicle taxes have been increased, the tax exemption on liquefied petroleum gas has been removed and allowances to deduct commuting expenses have been reduced. |
Structural vulnerabilities remain in the financial sector
The financial sector is dominated by large banks operating across Nordic countries, which manage large assets in relation to the size of the economies of the region. These banks are very profitable and strongly capitalised. However, liquidity buffers are low and concentration, interconnectedness and reliance on wholesale funding are high (Figure 11). To address these vulnerabilities, the government has proposed the introduction of a systemic risk buffer, which still has to be approved by Parliament. Nordea, the biggest Nordic bank, with assets of over twice Finland’s GDP, decided in September 2017 to move its headquarters to Helsinki to be under the common rules and regulations of the European banking union. Although job and tax gains may be limited, this raises the profile of Helsinki as a regional financial centre. This will require Finnish and European financial supervisors to adapt. As a global systemically important financial institution, Nordea will be supervised through the European Single Supervisory Mechanism, which involves the European Central Bank and the national supervisory authorities of the countries participating in the banking union. Ensuring efficient supervision will require adequate resources for supervisors and cooperation between countries where Nordea has a strong presence. The resources of the Finnish Financial supervisory authority (FIN-FSA) are being substantially increased, and the monitoring of financial developments in the Nordic region has been reinforced. The Nordic countries have recently signed new Memorandums of Understanding, which will strengthen cooperation on the supervision of significant bank branches. Nordea’s move would imply some risks for Finland in the unlikely case the bank were to experience financial difficulties. While recapitalisation could be provided through the European single resolutionfund, Finland guarantees the first EUR 100 000 of deposits as long as there is no European single deposit guarantee scheme (Bank of Finland, 2017a). The announcement of Danske Bank’s subsidiary conversion into a branch will also involve adjustments in supervision. The Nordic regulatory landscape could evolve further, especially if Denmark and/or Sweden decide to join the banking union.
Financial interconnections could propagate a shock hitting one of the Nordic countries, with real estate a particular area of concern, as it accounts for a large share of bank lending and valuations are high in many places. Real estate prices have increased rapidly in Norway and Sweden and household debt is high relative to income. In 2016, the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) issued warnings regarding medium-term housing market vulnerabilities and potential systemic risks to eight countries, including Denmark, Finland and Sweden (ESRB, 2016). The Swedish Financial supervisory authority has also warned about risks associated with commercial real estate in Sweden (Thedéen, 2017). Commercial real estate prices are volatile and have historically often played an important role in financial crises in the Nordics and elsewhere. A real estate collapse in other Nordic countries could affect Finland through weakening regional financial institutions.
In Finland, the household debt-to-income ratio is relatively high in an OECD perspective, but much lower than in the other Nordic countries (Figure 12, Panel A). This partly reflects a more conservative behaviour of borrowers and financial institutions, in particular in terms of amortisation of loans. Housing prices have been relatively stable over the past decade (Panel B), although increases have been relatively stronger in the Helsinki region than in other parts of the country. However, as economic performance improves while interest rates remain low, housing price growth could accelerate in metropolitan areas. Hence, it is necessary to have the right macro-prudential framework in place to be able to respond rapidly, should the housing market overheat. A binding maximum mortgage loan-to-value ratio of 90% (95% for first-time buyers) came into force in 2016. A minimum 15% risk weight on mortgages is set to apply from 2018. As loan-to-value ratios tend to be pro-cyclical, a loan-to-income or a debt service-to-income limit would be a useful complement. Mortgage amortisation should also be monitored closely, as an increase in non-amortising loans could increase risks for households and financial institutions. Finally, against a backdrop of stagnating income, Finnish households have increasingly been using consumer credit, including from foreign online providers and peer-to-peer lending services (Bank of Finland, 2017b). Even though consumer debt accounts for only 12% of total household debt and the bulk of it is still held by credit institutions, these developments require monitoring, both from a financial stability perspective and to ensure adequate consumer protection. Establishing a positive credit registry would facilitate underwriting of loans and monitoring of risks.
Table 6. Past recommendations on financial stability
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
The macro-prudential tools available to the authorities could include caps on mortgage loan-to-value ratios and higher risk weights on mortgages to prevent potentially unsustainable developments in household debt. |
A binding maximum mortgage loan-to-value ratio of 90% (95% for first-time buyers) was introduced in 2016. A minimum 15% risk weight on mortgages is set to apply from 2018. |
Public finances are under pressure from an ageing population
The budget deficit has fallen from a peak of 3.2% of GDP in 2014 to less than 2% of GDP in 2016 (Figure 13, Panel A) and likely shrank further in 2017. Fiscal consolidation has largely been achieved through spending containment. The positive impact of strengthening output growth on general government revenue has been partly offset by tax and social contribution cuts, amounting to 0.8% of GDP in 2017. After increasing rapidly over the past decade, government debt is stabilising, but gross debt (Maastricht definition) is over 60% of GDP (Panel B). The overall impact of budget measures over the period 2017-19 is fairly small (Table 7). Unless steps are taken to contain the increase in ageing-related costs or offset it through other tax or spending measures, debt will start rising again. Cost containment, as could be achieved by a successful health care and social services reform, would rein in debt. Halving the growth rate of spending on health care and social services compared to the no policy change scenario would leave debt close to 65% in 2030. A higher employment rate as a result of labour market reforms would bring debt down further (Figure 14).
Table 7. Impact of budget measures
Measure |
Budget impact (% of GDP) |
||
---|---|---|---|
2017 |
2018 |
2019 |
|
Reduction in personal income tax |
-0.3 |
-0.2 |
0.0 |
Reduction in social security contributions |
-0.5 |
-0.1 |
0.1 |
Reduction in expenditure |
0.9 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
Source: Ministry of Finance.
Table 8. Past recommendations on fiscal policy
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Consolidate public finances gradually as planned by the government by curbing public expenditure growth. |
The deficit has been reduced to less than 2% of GDP in 2016 and government expenditure adjusted for inflation has declined in 2015 and 2016. |
Table 9. Past recommendations on health care
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Rationalise the organisation of health services to achieve a better balance between primary and specialised care. |
A reform of health, social services and regional government set to enter into force on 1 January 2020 will shift most responsibilities for service provision from municipalities to new autonomous regions, creating opportunities for economies of scale and more equal access to services. |
Drawing on existing experiences in some municipalities, a purchaser-provider split should be adopted in areas where the population base and the level of complexity of treatment allow meaningful competition. |
The new social welfare and health care areas will be allowed to use private or third-sector service providers. Competitive neutrality between different providers will be emphasised. A scorecard will be prepared for assessing the efficiency and quality of service provision. |
Reforms to the tax system would enhance growth
The Finnish welfare model, which has fostered strong inclusive growth until the global financial crisis, is facing challenges, in particular with respect to population ageing, which both increases spending pressures by several percentage points of GDP over the next decades and reduces the economic growth potential (Figure 15). Meanwhile, globalisation increases the mobility of tax bases, making it more difficult to fund welfare in a fair and efficient way. Addressing these challenges will require both enhancing the efficiency of public services, including through regular spending reviews, and ensuring that the tax and benefit system supports growth, competitiveness and employment, while preserving its ability to contain income inequality. Increasing environmentally-related taxation and cutting environmentally-harmful subsidies would foster greener growth. Tax revenue as a share of GDP is among the highest in the OECD and comparable to the other Nordic countries (Figure 16).
The large government size reflects extensive income redistribution, the provision of a wide range of public services, as well as high public social spending (Figure 17, Panel A). As the distribution of tasks between the public and private sector varies widely across countries, a more accurate assessment of welfare costs is given by total net social spending, which includes both public social expenditure and private social spending (e.g. private pensions or health care insurance benefits) and takes taxation of benefits into account (Adema et al., 2011). On this measure, social spending in Finland is not as high relative to other countries, even though it is still above the OECD average (Panel B).
Raising property taxes and moving further towards tenure-neutral taxation of housing
Recurrent taxes on immovable property are generally considered as among the least harmful to economic growth (Arnold et al., 2011; Johansson, 2016). In addition, reducing the tax bias in favour of home-ownership and linking property taxes to regularly updated property valuations could reduce housing price volatility (Blöchliger et al., 2015a). Finland has been moving towards more even taxation of owner-occupiers and renters over recent years. In 2014, property assessment values were revised, and further updating to bring cadastral values closer to market values is expected to be completed by the early 2020s. The lower and higher thresholds of the range within which municipalities may set their property tax rate have been increased in steps. Mortgage interest deductibility from personal income tax is being gradually reduced, as in a number of other EU countries such as the Netherlands and Spain.
Nevertheless, property tax revenue remains below the OECD average (Figure 18). Residential property taxes are also regressive, as municipalities with high average incomes tend to set lower tax rates. Hence, there seems to be potential to raise a larger share of local government revenue through property taxation, as well as to make the tax more progressive. Higher revenue from property taxes also strengthens the incentives for municipalities to zone more land for development and speed up planning processes, enhancing the responsiveness of housing supply to demand. Property taxes are generally unpopular, especially because they are highly visible and sometimes perceived as unfair, insofar as they are disconnected from the ability to pay. In particular, property taxes may put a heavy burden on asset-rich income-poor households. However, these problems can be and are sometimes mitigated by means-tested exemptions for low-income households or measures to alleviate liquidity constraints, such as tax deferral (Blöchliger, 2015b).
Reducing the scope of reduced VAT rates
Finland has a 24% standard VAT rate, which is among the highest in the OECD (Figure 19, Panel A), but a number of goods and services are taxed at lower rates. A 14% rate applies to food and restaurants. A 10% rate applies to a wide range of items, including books, pharmaceutical products, accommodation, passenger transport services and some sport and cultural activities. The VAT efficiency ratio (i.e. the ratio of actual VAT revenue to potential VAT revenue if all goods and services were taxed at the standard VAT rate) is only about 54%, slightly below the OECD average (Panel B). A number of countries achieve higher efficiency, even though Luxembourg and New Zealand are special cases, reflecting the VAT treatment of financial services and e-commerce in Luxembourg and the fact that public services are subject to VAT in New Zealand (OECD, 2016b).
The relatively low efficiency of Finnish VAT is mainly related to exemptions and reduced rates, as compliance is high (Thackray et al., 2015; CASE, 2016). Reduced VAT rates cost about EUR 2 billion (1% of GDP) in 2014 and are the second largest tax expenditure after the total of deductions related to income taxes (Economic Policy Council, 2014). In most cases, reduced rates are justified by social and equity objectives, which could generally be achieved at a lower cost using targeted instruments, for example means-tested allowances. Another argument often used to justify reduced VAT rates is to support labour-intensive economic activities, in particular restaurants. However, experience from both Finland and abroad suggest a limited impact (Harju and Kosonen, 2013; NIER, 2015; Conseil des Prélèvements Obligatoires, 2015). Furthermore, having several VAT rates generates administrative and compliance costs. This calls for narrowing the number of goods and services subject to reduced rates. Another option would be to tax all products subject to reduced rates at 14%, instead of taxing some at this rate and others at 10%. Such reforms would likely have distributional consequences, hurting low-income households, but this could be easily offset by slightly lower taxes on low-income households.
International cooperation is required to avoid a race to the bottom in business taxation
Business taxation is relatively similar across Nordic countries and moderate by OECD standards and Finland has a competitive corporate income tax (CIT) rate (Figure 20). It is crucial for taxation in small economies to remain competitive in order to attract investment or maintain activity in the country, even though other factors like proximity to markets, good infrastructure, labour force skills and interdependence of activities within value chains are at least equally important in location decisions (Ketokivi et al., 2017). High marginal corporate tax rates are linked with significantly lower long-term output level (Akgun et al., 2017). The Nordic countries have reduced CIT rates significantly over the years (Figure 21, Panel A). Nevertheless, corporate tax revenue has so far held up relatively well (Panel B). Denmark, Estonia, Norway and Sweden are planning to further alleviate corporate income tax in different ways over the coming years. More generally, the global trend is towards lower CIT rates, with 15 OECD countries having implemented or announced CIT rate cuts since 2016 (OECD, 2017d).
Finland, together with 70 other jurisdictions, signed the multilateral instrument (MLI) which is part of the OECD/G20 project on Base erosion and profit shifting (BEPS) in June 2017. The MLI will allow Finland to transpose BEPS recommendations directly into its existing network of tax treaties; it will thus reinforce the anti-avoidance arsenal which is already part of Finnish tax legislation and includes controlled foreign company rules to limit tax avoidance through the use of affiliates in low-tax jurisdictions, transfer pricing rules which follow OECD guidelines and interest deduction limitations which prevent profit shifting through debt financing. The restriction on intra-firm interest deductibility imposed in 2014 is estimated to have lowered the financial expenses of Finnish multinational companies by 25% to 30%, without noticeable effects on other profit shifting measures or real output (Harju et al., 2017).
Table 10. Past recommendations on tax reform
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Continue to lower the taxation of labour and increase recurrent taxes on personal immovable property and indirect taxes. |
Income taxes and social contributions have been reduced. Excise duties and property tax rates have increased. |
Phase out mortgage interest deductibility. |
Mortgage interest deductibility is being reduced in steps. |
Raise the revenue efficiency of the VAT by eliminating reduced VAT rates. |
No action taken. |
Work incentives need to be strengthened, while maintaining strong social protection
Employment is lower in Finland than in all the other Nordics, even though skill levels are higher despite somewhat weakening PISA results over recent years. Cyclical factors play a role, with significant employment losses following the Great Recession (Figure 22). The current economic upturn increases the chances of reaching the government’s 72% employment target by 2019, but this remains challenging. Moreover, Finland needs to boost employment further to counter ageing, strengthen public finances and increase well-being. And the potential to expand the labour force is considerable, with lower employment than the Nordic average for all gender-age groups. Men of all ages are less likely to be employed than in the other Nordics, but especially so in older cohorts. Women in childbearing age are much less likely to be employed than in Sweden and Norway, despite taxation applying to individual incomes and generous parental leave and childcare arrangements in all three countries (Figure 23; OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016; Economic Policy Council, 2017).
A number of recommendations made in the OECD Economic Survey of Finland 2016 to improve the labour market functioning, including with respect to education, activation policy, employment protection legislation and wage bargaining, have since been addressed by the government and social partners. Important steps have also been taken to improve work incentives for the unemployed.
But more needs to be done. A complex system built around the traditional employer-employee model will likely be increasingly challenged in a rapidly changing world of work, and work incentives can still be very weak for many individuals when different benefits and taxes interact. Working may therefore not always be the most attractive option, and disincentives may be compounded by work-related expenses, spouse income, the number and age of children, regional housing price differences and individual preferences. The benefit reform scenarios below are used to unmask weaknesses of the current system and to show how the general direction of reform affects incentives, inclusiveness and affordability – the policy trilemma at the heart of social insurance and redistribution policy. These and similar analyses can serve to help formulate a vision for social welfare in Finland and to give a clear direction for benefit reform. However, major reorganisations can come with significant costs. Implementation should hence be stepwise, building on the existing system and institutional context, and important technical building blocks should be fully operational and well-tested before full roll-out.
Incentive- and bureaucratic traps in the current system
Finland has one of the highest tax wedges in the OECD, even though the tax wedge may be underestimated in some countries, where some mandatory social contributions are not taken into account (Figure 24). On the basis of recent OECD estimates (Égert and Gal, 2017), lowering the tax wedge to the level of the OECD average (holding the government budget balance constant) would raise GDP per capita by more than 2.5% after 10 years. Lowering it to the level of Sweden would raise GDP per capita by 1.8% after 10 years.
The tax wedge interacts with a patchwork of different working-age benefits introduced over the years to cater for different needs and insure against different circumstances. The combination of different working-age benefits, childcare costs and income taxation continues to create multiple incentive traps in OECD countries. Average effective tax rates can exceed 100% in some OECD countries, including Finland, and average effective tax rates above 80%, which also constitute weak incentives, are quite common (Figure 25).
Finland is no exception, with major disincentives appearing when unemployment, housing and social assistance benefits interact, and compounded by income taxation. A homecare allowance and a childcare fee designed as an additional income tax further reduce the pay-off from going from benefits to work for parents. “Bureaucratic traps”, where complex benefit rules combined with administrative practices create a real or perceived risk of losing eligibility or delayed benefit payments, can further reduce the attractiveness of work for risk-adverse, often cash-strapped, Finnish benefit recipients (Pareliussen et al., 2018).
Social protection needs to be fit for the future of work
Digitalisation, automation and globalisation have led to profound changes in working life over the past few decades, and will continue to do so going forward (Figure 26). Evidence of under-qualification and under-skilling is mainly found for older workers in Finland, which may call for strengthening lifelong learning, although participation in adult education is among the highest in the OECD (OECD, 2017e). Conversely, younger generations are more likely to be over-qualified and over-skilled (Pareliussen, 2016). Adapting the social safety net to the future of work and treating freelancers and self-employed as far as possible on an equal footing with regular workers is a major challenge to social protection systems across the OECD, but not an insurmountable one. And technology can help. The opportunities from freelancing and platform work should be welcomed by public employment services, and technology can facilitate automation of benefit payments, if they are linked to a real-time registry of incomes, as planned in Finland from 2020 (OECD, 2016c; OECD, 2017f).
Finding direction for benefit reform
Two benefit reform scenarios have been developed to explore how benefit design affects trade-offs between incentives, inclusiveness and affordability. In a basic income scenario, a lump-sum benefit replaces a number of existing benefits, financed by increasing income taxation by nearly 30% or around 4% of GDP. It provides basic security for all, hence simplifying the benefit system and making coverage universal. A second scenario, inspired by the universal credit in the United Kingdom, but adapted to the Finnish context, harmonises tapering rules for the current set of working-age benefits by merging them into one single benefit, tapered against net income with one single taper rate. Furthermore, it abolishes the link between public childcare and the homecare allowance and changes the childcare fee structure (Pareliussen et al., 2018).
Both scenarios can realistically be implemented without increasing net fiscal expenditure, although the basic income requires significant increases to income taxation. Both resolve some serious incentive issues in the current system (Table 11). However, a revenue-neutral scenario with the basic income set approximately at the level of the on-going basic income trial (Box 3) would imply significant redistribution of income, as the basic income is higher for couples than singles compared to the current system with benefits targeted to specific circumstances, unemployment insurance is abolished, benefit take-up increases and taxation changes. Overall, the basic income scenario increases the Gini coefficient by approximately 0.4 percentage points. The poverty rate increases from 11.4% to 14.1%, and of the 150 000 persons falling below the poverty line, 30 000 are children, and 50 000 early pensioners. In contrast, in the universal credit scenario, the Gini coefficient falls by 0.9 percentage points, and 90 000 people exit poverty, thereby reducing the poverty rate by 1.7 percentage points to 9.7% (Figure 27). It alleviates complexity and strengthens work incentives consistently for a variety of individual circumstances.
It should be noted that these results depend on the assumptions underlying the scenarios. The basic income for example is designed as one uniform benefit for all, in line with what is commonly associated with the term. Other lump-sum benefit structures, more targeted towards individuals in need, would likely perform better along the inequality dimension.
Table 11. Reform could reduce average effective tax rates
A. In %, individual entitled to unemployment insurance1
Household type |
Going back to work full time with 100% of previous earnings |
Going back to work full time with 80% of previous earnings |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Current system |
Basic income |
Universal credit |
Current system |
Basic income |
Universal credit |
|
Single |
79.1 |
72.0 |
73.4 |
89.4 |
78.3 |
72.2 |
Single parent |
97.7 |
86.2 |
73.4 |
99.5 |
91.4 |
72.2 |
Single earner in childless couple |
86.5 |
68.2 |
73.4 |
90.3 |
73.6 |
72.2 |
Single earner in couple with children |
88.3 |
74.4 |
73.4 |
93.8 |
81.3 |
72.2 |
Second earner in childless couple |
74.6 |
43.9 |
64.8 |
83.7 |
43.2 |
71.5 |
Second earner in couple with children |
102.0 |
66.1 |
73.4 |
118.0 |
71.0 |
72.2 |
B. In %, individual only entitled to social assistance and housing benefit2
Household type |
Half time |
Full time |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Current system |
Basic income |
Universal credit |
Current system |
Basic income |
Universal credit |
|
Single |
87.6 |
87.9 |
69.1 |
72.0 |
72.0 |
72.0 |
Single parent |
67.6 |
92.5 |
69.1 |
77.1 |
86.2 |
73.4 |
Single earner in childless couple |
87.6 |
87.9 |
69.1 |
86.5 |
68.2 |
73.4 |
Single earner in couple with children |
87.6 |
87.9 |
69.1 |
80.6 |
74.4 |
73.4 |
Second earner in childless couple |
11.6 |
41.9 |
11.6 |
24.0 |
43.9 |
24.0 |
Second earner in couple with children |
89.4 |
86.3 |
56.0 |
66.6 |
66.1 |
46.3 |
1. Previous earnings equal to 67% of national average wage. Means-tested benefits are allowed as top-ups. Households with children are assumed to have two children aged two and five. The person is going into work in the initial phase of unemployment. This implies that individuals in the current system and the universal credit scenario are entitled to an increased income-related allowance, resulting in somewhat higher average effective tax rates than without this allowance. See Pareliussen et al. (2018) for a detailed explanation and comparisons of incentives with and without the increased allowance.
2. Hourly wage equal to 67% of the national average wage. Households with children are assumed to have two children aged two and five.
Source: Simulations with the OECD TaxBen model, in Pareliussen et al. (2018).
Box 3. The Finnish basic income trial
A basic income is a uniform benefit to all, regardless of their earnings or individual circumstances. The concept of a basic income is not new, and most OECD countries already include unconditional transfers to certain groups in the form of, for example, child benefits and basic old-age pensions. However, the idea of such a benefit for the whole population has gained renewed attention lately as a possible way to adapt to challenges facing traditional social protection systems, such as the rise of atypical forms of employment and risk of job losses due to automation by way of simplification, improved work incentives and coverage.
In Finland, a lively academic and political debate about the subject eventually led to the implementation of a two-year basic income trial, which started in January 2017. The experiment covers 2 000 recipients of unemployment assistance, and converts the EUR 560 a month (before tax) unemployment assistance into an unconditional benefit in the sense that tapering and mandatory activation and job search requirements are abolished for the individuals concerned.
In the trial, income taxation and other benefits are kept unchanged, so that no participant loses out compared to the current system. This would be too costly to implement on a national scale: if existing spending on all working-age benefits was distributed with an equal amount to all, the benefit level would only constitute 13% of the median income, or 26% of the relative poverty threshold. Financing a basic income at a meaningful level thus would require considerable additional tax revenue, and heavier taxation of income would at least partially undo any improvement in work incentives.
Source: OECD, 2017a.
Reform priorities within the current system
Moving in the direction of coordinated benefit tapering, as illustrated in the universal credit scenario, would thus balance incentives, affordability and social protection, in line with Finnish social preferences. However, such reform should be gradual, as major welfare reforms can come with significant costs (Fimreite et al., 2012; NAO, 2013). In this process, important technical building blocks should be fully operational and well-tested before full roll-out, and resolving specific incentive issues should be prioritised over immediate, full‐fledged benefit reform.
One such issue arises because unemployment insurance benefits are fully withdrawn when working more than 80% of full time, resulting in a “cliff-edge” loss of income (Figure 28). The cliff-edge loss of benefits can strongly disincentivise full-time work, and should be abolished. Somewhat higher tapering on low incomes combined with a lower initial benefit level could make the 80% limit obsolete, and is hence an alternative solution, but would entail a trade-off with somewhat weaker protection and weaker incentives to take up part-time jobs.
The existence of a time limit to the earnings-related unemployment insurance increases incentives to go back to work, including when the earnings-related unemployment insurance runs out (Figure 29), but actually mainly earlier on in the unemployment spell. The reduction in benefit duration by 100 days in January 2017 is estimated to reduce average time in unemployment by 10%, increase employment significantly, and lead to fiscal savings of more than EUR 100 million. Increasing inequality from lower benefit payments is expected to be neutralised by job creation (Kyyrä et al., 2017a and b; Ministry of Finance, 2017b; Kotamäki et al., 2017). A new activity requirement from January 2018, stipulating that those who do not work or participate in activation activities for at least 18 hours during each three-month period following unemployment will get their unemployment insurance reduced by 4.5% in the following three-month period, may trigger similar threshold effects earlier in the unemployment spell (Ministry of Finance, 2017c).
Making work pay for parents
The homecare allowance is equivalent to a direct subsidy to stay out of the workforce for parents, notably second earners (OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016). To remove disincentives, the direct link to participation in childcare needs to be broken. Such a restructuring could be achieved by removing the allowance as it is today, while at least partially compensating losers by increasing the basic parental leave amount. In order to preserve the free choice to stay at home with young children up to three years, as the combination of parental leave and homecare allowance allows in the current system, parents should have the option to extend the parental leave duration while lowering the monthly benefit accordingly.
Individual income taxation in Finland strongly incentivises work for second earners. However, the childcare fee is designed as an additional income tax calculated on family income. Gains to second earners entering work can hence be strongly reduced by the fee, and may even be negative in some circumstances. The government reduced the childcare fee for families with two or more children in public childcare by approximately 20% from 2017. Although a significant step in the right direction, resolving the current incentive issues requires a more profound restructuring. Calculating the childcare fee on the basis of the lowest-earning spouses’ income is a possible solution which, combined with a restructuring of the homecare allowance, would profoundly transform work incentives for second earner parents (Figure 30).
Shortening the unemployment tunnel for older workers
As in many other European countries, older unemployed are entitled to longer periods on unemployment insurance benefits, effectively providing a bridge to retirement. In Finland, those aged above 61 on the day their unemployment insurance expires qualify for extended unemployment benefits until the statutory pension age – the “unemployment tunnel” (Kyyrä and Pesola, 2017; OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016).
A pension reform taking effect in 2017 raises the statutory pension age gradually from 63 to 65 before linking it to life expectancy from 2030 onwards, and increases the age threshold for the unemployment tunnel from 61 to 62 years. Increasing the pension age has put the pension system on a sustainable trajectory, but ageing costs are still expected to show up in unemployment, health and long-term care expenditures. The unemployment tunnel is expected to reduce the overall employment effect of the pension reform (Economic Policy Council, 2015). A previous increase in the age threshold increased employment and individual net income considerably, as individuals covered by the new rules postponed retirement by an average of seven months (Figure 31). Furthermore, it resulted in considerable fiscal savings and no negative spill-over effects were found (Kyyrä and Pesola, 2017). To consolidate employment gains from the pension reform, the unemployment tunnel threshold should at least increase in line with the statutory pension age, and access to other routes to early retirement should be restricted (OECD Economic Survey of Finland, 2016).
Ensuring smooth transitions between work and benefits
Recent centralisation of benefit administration in the Social Insurance Institution of Finland (Kela) and major simplifications to the housing benefit are important first steps towards benefit harmonisation. Further simplification and improved incentives could be achieved by merging the housing benefit and the social assistance housing supplement, reducing the social assistance taper rate and coordinate the tapering of the two. It is also worth considering incentives that would push tenants who receive housing support through social assistance to look for housing with lower rents. Further harmonisation of the tax treatment and income definitions of benefits could pave the way for restructuring benefits into their core functions: a personal basic amount, a child supplement, a housing supplement and an unemployment insurance supplement, with coordinated tapering as described in the universal credit scenario.
In the short to intermediate term, a combination of timely benefit decisions when individual circumstances change and extending rights to full benefits for a limited period of time after taking up work would go a long way in removing bureaucratic traps. The basic unemployment benefit can be used as a mobility and wage subsidy as of 2017, which is a step in this direction. Furthermore, the government plans to extend unemployment benefits for four months to recipients who start an entrepreneurial activity (Ministry of Finance, 2017c). Real-time coordination of earnings and benefits is planned with the new real-time income registry as from 2020. The registry, coupled with on-line user tools, will improve transparency and holds the potential to provide seamless transitions between work and benefits even when the underlying benefit rules are complex. Strengthened work incentives combined with real-time coordination of benefits and earnings and a strong activation framework, would make for a truly efficient and inclusive benefit system.
Active labour market policies
The number of unemployed per caseworker more than doubled from 2008 (Figure 32), putting the employment service under strain. New initiatives, such as job-search and reporting requirements and more frequent meetings with caseworkers, are positive, but their follow-up requires additional resources. Funding for the employment service increased in 2017, and shifting some funding from relatively expensive activation programmes towards more and earlier face-to-face contact with a jobseeker should be considered. Effective activation of non-standard workers requires equal quality of activation policies for all workless, regardless of which benefit they receive. Furthermore, “in-work progression” services could be considered, for example by offering training and mentoring to individuals in non-standard or unstable employment (OECD, 2016d; OECD, 2015b; OECD, 2017f).
As part of the 2020 health, social services and regional government reform, 18 new regions will take over the responsibility for employment services, which they will purchase from public, private and third-sector providers. This reform represents a leap into uncharted territory, and its success depends on a number of factors, including the development of the necessary IT infrastructure and appropriate procurement models and systems to ensure quality in provision, foster competition and avoid cream-skimming from service providers. Furthermore, funding for the new regions will not be earmarked to different purposes. Hence, there is a risk that overruns in healthcare or social expenditures could crowd out funding for employment services. A shift towards payments to providers based on employment outcomes, as signalled in the 2018 budget proposal, has shown some merit in initial trials (OECD, 2016d) and a similar model targeted towards immigrants is being trialled, where returns to investors in a “social impact bond” are tied to participants gaining employment. Such experiments provide useful experience in preparation for the 2020 regional reform.
Conclusions from the benefit simulations
The combination of different working-age benefits, childcare costs and income taxation creates complexity, reduces work incentives and holds back employment. Major disincentives in Finland are related to tapering rules for unemployment benefits, social assistance and the housing benefit, the extended unemployment benefit for older workers, the childcare fee structure and the homecare allowance. Improved benefit design combined with efficient activation policies can reduce complexity and remove the strongest disincentives. Comparing two different scenarios – a uniform benefit for all (“basic income”) versus a universal tapering rule (“universal credit”) – shows how much the general direction of reform matters, as they lead to considerable differences in incentives, inclusiveness and affordability.
The current benefit system targets transfers according to people’s needs and circumstances. For this reason, replacing current benefits with a basic income, a uniform benefit for all, would lead to a drastic redistribution of income and likely increase poverty, even though it would entail a simplification and improve incentives for some.
Merging working-age benefits with similar aims and coordinating their tapering against earnings would on the other hand drastically improve work incentives and transparency, while preserving or strengthening social protection. Moving the benefit system step by step in this direction therefore seems to be a solution better adapted to Finland than implementing a basic income. Once the new income registry comes online, linking benefit payments to real-time incomes, combined with strengthened work incentives and a strong activation framework, would make for a truly efficient and inclusive benefit system, fit for the future of work.
Table 12. Past recommendations on labour market reform
Main recent OECD recommendations |
Action taken since the 2016 Survey or planned |
---|---|
Reduce the combined duration of parental leave and the homecare allowance to encourage female labour market participation. |
No action taken. |
Shorten the duration of the unemployment benefit and reduce benefits over the unemployment spell. Systematically enforce mandatory job-search and reporting requirements starting early in the unemployment spell. |
The unemployment benefit duration has been cut by 100 days, and mandatory job-search and activation requirements introduced. |
Strengthen the roles of the state mediator and of the local level of unions in the wage setting process to raise local flexibility without compromising competitiveness. |
Legislation to extend the scope for local-level agreement has been passed. As part of the competitiveness pact, coordinated sector-wise bargaining is set to replace the tri-partite central agreement as the main wage-setting model. |
Strengthen foundation skills in vocational education and training (VET), |
A new core curriculum puts more emphasis on foundation skills, the VET programme structure has been reformed, with fewer and broader qualifications, and a new structure of modular qualifications is to be implemented in VET, universities and universities of applied science. |
Bibliography
Adema, W., P. Fron and M. Ladaique (2011), “Is the European welfare State really more expensive? Indicators on social spending, 1980-2012; and a Manual to the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX)”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 124, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kg2d2d4pbf0-en.
Akgun, O., B. Cournède and J.M. Fournier (2017), “The effects of the tax mix on inequality and growth”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1447, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/c57eaa14-en.
Arnold, J., B. Brys, C. Heady, Å. Johansson, C. Schwellnus and L. Vartia (2011), “Tax policy for economic recovery and growth”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 121, No. 550.
Bank of Finland (2017a), Financial Stability Assessment: Finland’s Banking Sector Expands – Banking Union Mitigates Risks, Helsinki.
Bank of Finland (2017b), Bank of Finland Bulletin 2-2017, Helsinki.
Blöchliger, H. et al. (2015a), “The stabilisation properties of immovable property taxation: Evidence from OECD countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1237, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5js0cqq93djg-en.
Blöchliger, H. (2015b), “Reforming the tax on immovable property: Taking care of the unloved”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1205, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5js30tw0n7kg-en.
Bragadóttir, H. et al. (2014), The Use of Economic Instruments in Nordic Environmental Policy 2010-2013, TemaNord 2014:549, Nordic Council of Ministers, Copenhagen.
CASE (2016), Study and Reports on the VAT Gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2016 Final Report, Center for Social and Economic Research, Warsaw.
Conseil des Prélèvements Obligatoires (2015), La taxe sur la valeur ajoutée, Paris.
de la Maisonneuve, C. and J. Oliveira Martins (2013), “A projection method for public health and long-term care expenditures”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1048, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k44v53w5w47-en.
Economic Policy Council (2015), Economic Policy Council Report 2014, Economic Policy Council, VATT Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki.
Economic Policy Council (2017), Economic Policy Council Report 2016, Economic Policy Council, VATT Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki.
Égert, B. and P. Gal (2017), “The quantification of structural reforms in OECD countries: A new framework”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1354, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/2d887027-en.
ESRB (2016), Vulnerabilities in the EU Residential Real Estate Sector, European Systemic Risk Board, Frankfurt am Main.
European Commission (2017), Country Report Finland 2017, Commission Staff Working Document, No. 2017/91, Brussels.
Fimreite, A. et al. (2012), “Joined-up-government: Reform challenges, experiences and accountability relations”, Uni Rokkan Centre Working Paper No. 6-2012.
Gibney, E. (2015), “Why Finland now leads the world in nuclear waste storage”, Nature.
Guillemette, Y. et al. (2017), “A revised approach to productivity convergence in long-term scenarios”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1385, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/0b8947e3-en.
Harding, M. (2014), “The diesel differential: Differences in the tax treatment of gasoline and diesel for road use”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 21, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jz14cd7hk6b-en
Harju, J. and T. Kosonen (2013), “Restaurant VAT cut: Cheaper meal and more service?”, VATT Working Papers, No. 52, Government Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki.
Harju, J., I. Kauppinen and O. Ropponen (2017), “Firm responses to an interest barrier: Empirical evidence”, VATT Working Papers, No. 90, Government Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki.
Hyyrynen, M. (2013), Environmentally Harmful Subsidies, Reports of the Ministry of the Environment, 13/2013, Ministry of the Environment, Helsinki (in Finnish).
Johansson, Å. (2016), “Public finance, economic growth and inequality: A survey of the evidence”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1346, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/094bdaa5-en.
Ketokivi, M. et al. (2017), “Why locate manufacturing in a high-cost country? A case study of 35 production location decisions”, Journal of Operations Management, Vol. 49-51.
Kotamäki, M., J. Mattila and J. Tervola (2017), “Turning static pessimism to dynamic optimism. An ex ante evaluation of unemployment insurance reform in Finland”, Kela Working Papers, No. 124, Helsinki.
Kyyrä, K. et al. (2017a), “The spike at benefit exhaustion in the Finnish labor market”, VATT Working Papers, No. 86, Helsinki.
Kyyrä, K. et al. (2017b), “Unemployment insurance in Finland: A review of recent changes and empirical evidence on behavioral responses”, VATT Research Reports, No. 184, Helsinki.
Kyyrä, K. and H. Pesola (2017), “Long-term effects of extended unemployment benefits for older workers”, VATT Working Papers, No. 89, Helsinki.
Maliranta, M., N. Määttänen and M. Pajarinen (2016), “Firm subsidies, wages and labor mobility”, Research Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA) reports, No. 60, Helsinki.
Ministry of Finance (2016), Economic Survey, Autumn, Ministry of Finance publications 31c/2016, Helsinki.
Ministry of Finance (2017a), Outlook and Challenges for Finland’s Public Finances, Ministry of Finance publications 7b/2017, Helsinki.
Ministry of Finance (2017b), Europe 2020 Strategy, Finland’s National Programme, Spring 2017, Ministry of Finance Publications, 18c/2017, Helsinki.
Ministry of Finance (2017c), Hallituksen Esitys Eduskunnalle Valtion Talousarvioksi Vuodelle 2018 (The Government’s Proposal to Parliament on the 2018 State Budget), Helsinki.
Mirrlees, J. et al. (2011), Tax by Design: The Mirrlees Review, Oxford University Press.
National Audit Office (2013), Universal Credit: Early Progress, NAO reports, London.
National Institute for Health and Welfare (2017), Gender equality, Work webpage, www.thl.fi/en/web/gender-equality/gender-equality-in-finland/work, accessed on 23 August 2017.
NIER (2015), “Kort- och långsiktiga effekter av sänkt restaurangmoms”, Specialstudier Nr. 46, National Institute of Economic Research, Stockholm.
OECD (2012), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2012, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-fin-2012-en.
OECD (2014), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2014, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-fin-2014-en.
OECD (2015a), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264248533-en.
OECD (2015b), OECD Employment Outlook 2015, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/empl_outlook-2015-en.
OECD (2016a), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-fin-2016-en.
OECD (2016b), Consumption Tax Trends 2016: VAT/GST and Excise Rates, Trends and Policy Issues, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/cct-2016-en.
OECD (2016c), “New forms of work in the digital economy”, OECD Digital Economy Papers, No. 260, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jlwnklt820x-en.
OECD (2016d), Back to Work: Finland: Improving the Re-employment Prospects of Displaced Workers, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264264717-en.
OECD (2017a), “Basic income as a policy option: Can it add up?”, Policy Brief on the Future of Work, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2017b), OECD Reviews of Innovation Policy: Finland 2017, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264276369-en.
OECD (2017c), Pensions at a Glance 2017: OECD and G20 Indicators, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/pension_glance-2017-en.
OECD (2017d), Tax Policy Reforms in the OECD 2017, forthcoming.
OECD (2017e), Education at a Glance 2017: OECD Indicators, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eag-2017-en.
OECD (2017f), OECD Employment Outlook 2017, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/empl_outlook-2017-en.
Pareliussen, J. (2016), “Age, skills and labour market outcomes in Finland”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1321, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jlv23953gq1-en.
Pareliussen, J., H. Viitamäki and H. Hwang (2018), “Basic income or a single tapering rule? Incentives, inclusiveness and affordability compared for the case of Finland”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, forthcoming, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Prime Minister’s Office (2017), Finland, A Land of Solutions – Mid-Term Review, Government Action Plan 2017-2019, Government Publications 7/2017.
Thackray, M., E. Hutton, and K. Kapoor (2015), Finland, Revenue Administration Gap Analysis Program, The Value-Added Tax Gap, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Thedéen, E. (2017), “Finansinspektionen’s view on financial stability and the risks for financial imbalances”, Open Q&A in the Committee on Finance regarding financial supervision, 13 June.