In the context of the COVID-19 pandemic and resulting economic contraction and government debt build-up, the government is formulating reforms to raise employment by 80 thousand workers by 2029. Finland’s employment rate has been lagging behind the Scandinavian Nordics, with most of the gap attributable to older workers, who have more favourable access to early retirement schemes than their Scandinavian counterparts. To restrict their use, extended unemployment benefit, which is paid to unemployed persons aged 61 or more after normal unemployment benefit expires until they retire or reach 65, should be phased out and non-medical conditions should no longer be taken into account for disability benefit applications of persons aged 60 or more. Activity rates for mothers of young children are also lower in Finland than in the Scandinavian Nordics mainly owing to Finland’s generous homecare allowance. It should be reduced and access to convenient early childhood education and care services expanded to improve mothers’ work incentives. By increasing mothers’ work experience at critical points in their careers, such a reform would also help to narrow Finland’s large gender wage gap. As part of its 2021 budget, the government is setting out labour market reforms to increase employment by 31 to 36 thousand workers. Such reforms should focus on promoting employment of older workers.
OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2020
2. Realising the government’s objective to increase employment
Abstract
As described in the new OECD Jobs Strategy, Finland performs well in terms of job quality and inclusiveness of the labour market but not so well in some dimensions of job quantity (Box 2.1). In particular, the employment rate is lower than in the Scandinavian Nordics (Denmark, Norway and Sweden), which also have high levels of social cohesion and redistribution and are considered by Finns to be the most comparable countries, and the unemployment rate is higher than the OECD average. Prior to the COVID-19 crisis, the government had committed to implementing reforms to increase the employment rate from 73.4% of the working-age population (15-64 years) in 2023 on unchanged policies to 75%, slightly below the Scandinavian average. This increase, which corresponds to an increase of 60 000 in the number of people employed, was intended to help pay for the increases in social spending in the government’s programme. In the aftermath of the COVID-19 crisis, this employment rate target is unattainable. Instead, the government has committed to implementing reforms before the end of its term in office in 2023 to increase the number of people employed by 80 000 by 2029. If realised, this increase in employment would raise the employment rate from an estimated 70.8% in 2020 to 73.7% in 2029, reversing the labour market damage caused by COVID-19 and reducing, but not eliminating the structural budget deficit. The government is formulating reforms as part of the 2021 budget that it estimates would achieve a little less than a half of this employment objective (Box 2.2).
This chapter reviews essential policy measures for Finland to achieve its employment objective. The next section sets the scene by analysing the origins of the sizable gap in the employment rate between Finland and the Scandinavian Nordics and identifies the key target groups: older workers and mothers with young children. The following section reviews major reforms since the turn of the century to extend the working lives of older workers, including the government’s latest policy package to increase the employment rate. Section 3 provides policy recommendations to boost employment of older workers. It describes notable features of the unemployment and disability benefits system in Finland, in particular easier access to these benefits granted to older workers, which creates strong incentives for early retirement. Section 4 discusses measures to strengthen work incentives for mothers with young children.
Box 2.1. Finland’s labour market performance in the new OECD Jobs Strategy
Finland performs well in term of job quality and labour market inclusiveness, but lags behind the Scandinavian Nordics and, in some dimensions, the OECD average for job quantity (Figure 2.1). While the employment rate improved markedly over the past few years and is now higher than the OECD average, it remains lower than in the Scandinavian Nordics (see below). Finland’s high unemployment rate reflects high long-term unemployment that is rooted in weak work incentives and labour market mismatches (OECD, 2016[1]). Earnings quality is in the top third of OECD countries, while labour market insecurity and job strain are among the lowest in the OECD. Due to a compressed wage distribution and extensive redistribution, the share of working-age persons with less than 50% of the median household income is only 7%, a share that is smaller only in the Czech Republic, Switzerland and Iceland. Furthermore, the employment gap between disadvantaged groups and prime-age men is also significantly lower than the OECD average, albeit higher than in the Scandinavian Nordics. The gender labour income gap is among the lowest in the OECD, but this is driven by the small gender gaps in working hours and employment rates, while the gender pay gap among full-time employees is large (see below).
Box 2.2. The employment package for the 2021 budget negotiation
In the context of the 2021 budget negotiations, the government is formulating a comprehensive employment package that it estimates would generate 31,000–36,000 jobs by 2029, somewhat less than half the 80 000 objective. Additional measures will be decided during the government’s mid-term policy review session, to be held in Spring 2021. The employment package covers a wide range of measures, some of which were already included in the 2019 employment package (see below). The most important areas for reform include:
Increasing the employment rate of older workers. The social partners were tasked to propose measures to reduce the early retirement of workers aged 55 and over and increase their employment by between 10 000-12 000 by 2029 in a way that strengthens public finances, for instance by maintaining ability to work, skills and well-being throughout workers’ careers and avoiding disability. A new centre promoting lifelong learning in working life, which will help to maintain workers’ skills as they age, will be established in 2021. These measures would complement the increase in the minimum age when an unemployed person becomes entitled to an extension of the unemployment benefit from 61 currently to 62 from 2023. This reform, which was decided by the previous government and enacted in January 2020, is estimated to increase employment by up to 7 000 (see below).
Strengthening job search by unemployment benefit recipients. The government will introduce an obligation for unemployment benefit recipients to apply for up to four job opportunities every month. Failure to fulfil this obligation would result in the loss of five days’ worth of unemployment benefits. If repeated, the loss of unemployment benefits will increase gradually. In order to support more intensive job search, resources for the Public Employment Offices will be increased by EUR 70 million to strengthen job counselling services. These additional resources will allow the PES to contact unemployed job seekers every fortnight at an early stage of the unemployment period. The government expects these measures to increase employment by up to 10 000.
Reducing the fee for early childhood education services. The government will reduce client fees for early childhood education and care (ECEC) by EUR 70 million, which it estimates would increase employment by up to 3 600.
Other measures include facilitating the use of the wage subsidy scheme, adopting a linear model for partial disability pension that preserves work incentives for those on disability pension, overhauling apprenticeship training, establishing a new centre promoting lifelong learning in working life and improving educational attainment of the low-skilled population.
The employment rate gap between Finland and the Scandinavian Nordics
The employment rate of persons aged 15-64 in Finland was 73% in 2019, below the 76% average rate in the Scandinavian Nordics. Considering that they have much higher shares of immigrants, who have lower employment rates than the native-born (Box 2.3), Finland’s relative performance is even poorer than suggested by the headline figures and the potential for improvement correspondingly greater. By far the largest contribution to the employment rate gap is made by the 60-64 year-old age group, followed by young women (up to 35 years of age, although this gap mainly reflects differences in statistical classifications – see below) and youth (15-19 years old) (Figure 2.2, Panel A). The employment rate gap for 60-64 year olds is enormous, at 13 percentage points (Panel B) and reflects lower full-time employment rates in Finland when the split between full-time and part-time employment is made on a common definition (excluding Denmark from the Scandinavian Nordic average owing to a lack of data). Closing this gap would entail increasing employment by 48 000, which would go a long way to achieving the target 80 000 headcount employment increase. The employment rate of 65-69 year-olds (15%), who are outside the working-age population definition (15-64) used for the government’s employment objective, also lags far behind the Scandinavian Nordic average (25%).
Box 2.3. The native-born employment rate gap
The gap between employment rates in Finland and the Scandinavian Nordics is flattered by the lower share of immigrants in Finland’s population (6%) than the average for the other countries (14%). Employment rates for immigrants in all four countries are considerably lower than for the native-born (Table 2.1). For the native-born population, the employment rate gap is considerably larger than for the total population. Closing the native-born employment rate gap with the Scandinavian Nordic average would entail increasing this employment rate by 7.3 percentage points, corresponding to 185 000 jobs.
Table 2.1. The employment rate gap is much greater for the native-born- than the total population
Native-born |
Foreign-born |
Total |
|
---|---|---|---|
Finland |
72.8 |
62.2 |
72.2 |
Denmark |
77.0 |
66.4 |
74.3 |
Norway |
76.5 |
69.7 |
74.8 |
Sweden |
80.8 |
66.7 |
77.4 |
Average for the Scandinavian Nordics other than Finland |
78.1 |
67.6 |
75.5 |
Note: Share of persons aged 15-64. The data refer to 2018.
Source: OECD International Migration Statistics; and OECD Labour Force Statistics.
The shortfall in Finland’s employment rate relative to the Scandinavian Nordic average almost entirely reflects differences in age-group employment rates and only marginally differences in population age structure (Figure 2.3). Differences in age structure make almost no contribution to the female employment rate gap and only a small contribution to the male gap, reflecting the slightly larger share of older men in the working-age population in Finland than in the other countries.
The employment rate gap for older workers
The employment rate gap for 60-64 year olds reflects both a much lower labour force participation rate (Figure 2.4, Panel A), which is weighed down by labour market exit through early retirement pathways (see below), and a higher unemployment rate (Panel B). The participation- and unemployment rate gaps are considerably higher for men than for women. The effective retirement age, based on the average age of exit from the labour force of each five-year cohort aged over 40 during a five-year period, is lower (63.5) than in the Scandinavian Nordic countries (64.7) and the OECD average (64.4; Figure 2.5). The Finnish Centre for Pensions’ (FCP) estimate of the effective retirement age, which is based on the expected age at which people currently aged 25 will draw an earnings-related pension (old-age or disability), is somewhat lower, at 61.3 (61.6 for males and 60.9 for females). However, older workers drawing extended unemployment benefit (see below) are not considered to be retired according to this definition even though they effectively are.
The employment rate gap for 60-64 year olds declined sharply between 2004 and 2008, reflecting a faster increase in the employment rate in Finland than in the Scandinavian Nordics but has since been stable as the increase in the employment rate in Finland was matched in the other countries (Figure 2.6, Panel A). By contrast, the gap for 55-59 year olds has continued to narrow over the past decade, reflecting a much larger increase in the employment rate than in the Scandinavian Nordics (Panel B).
The employment rate gap for young women
The employment rate for young women (30 to 34) in Finland is 74%, 5.9 percentage points lower than the Scandinavian Nordic average, and 7.8 percentage points lower than in Sweden. However, this gap is overstated owing to differences in the statistical treatment of maternity leave beyond three months – women on such maternity leave are deemed to be out of the labour force in Finland but still employed in Sweden. A way to avoid this problem is to compare employment rates excluding women on maternity leave. This can be done by focusing on work attendance rates, which measure the share of persons who were at work during the survey week (Kambur and Pärnänen, 2017[2]). Measured by work attendance rates, the percentage of young women going to work in Finland is about the same as in Sweden, suggesting that the employment rate difference is an artefact.
Nevertheless, work attendance rates for young mothers are considerably lower in Finland than Sweden for mothers of children aged up to three years old (Figure 2.7, Panel A). This pattern is especially noticeable when the youngest child is over one year old - the difference is only 3.5 percentage points when the youngest child is aged less than one but increases to 15 percentage points when the youngest child is between one and three years old. It is thus more common for mothers to return to work when their child is one year old in Sweden than in Finland. The opposite holds for fathers, who are more likely to continue working when their children are younger than three years old in Finland than in Sweden (Panel B) – Finnish fathers take less parental leave than their Swedish counterparts. The share of mothers of young children working part-time is also much lower in Finland than Sweden, narrowing the gap in terms of hours worked. Whereas around half of mothers work part-time in Sweden when the child is aged one or two years old, this share is only one quarter in Finland.
The employment rate gap for youth
The youth (aged 15-19 years) employment rate in Finland is 28%, 7 percentage points lower than the Scandinavian Nordic average. However this gap is driven by Denmark, where much vocational education at the upper secondary level occurs through apprenticeships, in contrast to arrangements in Finland, Norway and Sweden. As a result, a higher share of people in vocational education are employed in Denmark than in the other countries. Excluding Denmark, the Scandinavian Nordic average youth employment rate is the same as in Finland. As the youth employment rate gap reflects differences in the way that vocational education is delivered in Denmark rather than poor labour market performance and the small numbers of youth in the labour force, this gap is not discussed further in this chapter.
Reforms since the turn of the century to increase employment
Tightening access to disability pension and increasing the share of employers subject to experience-rated contributions
Disability benefit has acted as a pathway to early retirement in Finland (see below). In 2004, the government tightened eligibility conditions by abolishing the Individual Early Retirement (IER) scheme, which applied lenient medical criteria for employees aged 60 and over with a long working career; the IER did not define the minimum degree of working incapacity or consider working possibilities other than the current job or occupation. As a result of this reform, the share of claim rejections rose and the share of new retirees being granted a disability pension declined by nearly 10 percentage points (de la Maisonneuve et al., 2014[3]). The share of disability benefits in total pension expenditure fell from more than 18% in 2003 to about 13% in 2011. The reform is also estimated to have lengthened the working lives of older workers by 3.4 months (Kyyrä, 2015[4]). Furthermore, it may have contributed to the decline after 2004 in the employment gap of 60-64 year olds between Finland and other Scandinavian Nordics (Figure 2.6, Panel A). At the same time, the reform introduced some non-medical eligibility criteria for disability benefit for those aged 60 and over, which still facilitate early retirement.
Until 1995, firms with more than 300 employees were required to pay a lump-sum payment to the insurance provider that amounts to a given share of a new disability benefit claim by their former employees, while those below the size threshold paid a uniform fixed tariff for each employee. A reform in 1995 lowered the size threshold, making mid-sized firms with 50 to 300 employees liable to this lump-sum payment. This reform reduced transitions to sickness benefits and further transitions from sickness benefits to disability benefits (Korkeamäki and Kyyrä, 2012[5]), suggesting that that higher disability benefit costs encouraged employers to invest in sickness prevention measures and to accommodate employees with health problems in the workplace. Since 2006, the lump-sum payments have been replaced by partially experience-rated disability insurance premiums. The effect of this scheme in reducing the inflow into disability benefits is ambiguous (Kyyrä and Paukkeri, 2018[6]). The survey of employers conducted by the Finnish Centre for Pensions indicates that employers find the current experience-rating system complex (Liukko et al., 2017[7]), implying that they may not be well aware of the extent to which they could reduce their contributions by making greater efforts to prevent worker disability.
Increasing the age of entitlement to extended unemployment benefit
Finland offers generous unemployment benefit entitlements to older workers that are longer than those for younger workers and can also be extended up to the statutory retirement age (Box 2.4). This extension, often dubbed as the unemployment tunnel, provides an attractive pathway to early retirement. The unemployment rate rises sharply in Finland for workers near the age at which they are entitled to the unemployment tunnel. The eligibility age has been raised gradually over time, from 55 before 1997 for all workers to the current 61 for those born in or after 1957. The age threshold is to increase to 62 for those born in 1961 or after. These reforms have pushed back the timing of the sharp rise in unemployment, effectively lengthening the working lives of older workers (see below).
Box 2.4. Unemployment benefits in Finland
Unemployment benefits in Finland consist of earnings-related Unemployment Insurance benefits (ansiosidonnainen päiväraha), a flat-rate basic unemployment allowance (peruspäiväraha) and a flat-rate means-tested labour market subsidy (työmarkkinatuki).
Earnings-related benefits, which comprise a flat-rate basic part (EUR 33.66 per day in 2020) and an earnings-related component, are paid to unemployment insurance fund members satisfying the employment condition (those having worked and paid contributions for at least 26 weeks within the last 28 months); the funds pay 6% of the costs of earnings-related benefits with the rest coming from social security contributions and general taxation. Although membership is not compulsory, 84% of employees were enrolled in unemployment funds in 2012 (Shin and Böckerman, 2020[8]). Non-members of unemployment funds can receive the flat-rate basic unemployment allowance (EUR 33.66 per day in 2020) from the Social Security Institution (Kela) if they satisfy the same employment condition. Those eligible to neither earnings-related benefits nor basic unemployment allowance, because they do not satisfy the employment condition or used up the maximum payment period of basic or earnings-related unemployment benefits (see below), can receive a labour market subsidy (EUR 33.66 per day in 2020) from Kela.
The earnings-related component of earnings-related unemployment benefit is 45% of the difference between the past daily wage and the base part of the benefit for the unemployed previously receiving monthly wages of EUR 3 198 or lower. For those receiving higher monthly wages, the replacement rate of 45% is applied up to the income threshold and then a lower replacement ratio of 20% is applied to the exceeding amount. Slightly higher replacement rates are applied to the unemployed with a child and those participating in activation programmes. In practice, overall replacement rates of around 60% have been most common (Kyyrä, Pesola and Rissanen, 2017[9]).
The earnings-related and basic unemployment benefits are paid for a maximum of 400 days (300 days for those who have worked less than three years). However, workers aged 58 years or more who worked at least five years in the past 20 years are entitled to a maximum of 500 weekdays of benefits. Furthermore, those aged 61 years (62 years from 2023) or older when reaching their 500-days benefit limit qualify for an extension until the retirement age of 65.
Unemployment benefits can be combined with work. The unemployed taking up full-time work for less than two weeks or part-time work can qualify for partial benefits. The days on which partial benefits are paid are only counted partially toward the maximum benefit duration, but the working days are counted into the employment condition if the weekly working time is at least 18 hours.
Note: Daily wage is computed by dividing the monthly wage by 21.5.
Source: The Social Security Institution (Kela), (Kyyrä, Pesola and Rissanen, 2017[9]).
Employers share part of the benefit costs (the liability component) when their former employee receives extended unemployment benefit (Box 2.5). Before 2000, firms with more than 300 employees were liable for 50% of the present value of the unemployment pension benefits (the equivalent of extended unemployment benefit at the time) while firms with 50 to 300 workers paid 0% to 50% of the expected benefits depending on their size. A reform implemented in 2000 strengthened this liability component by raising the maximum liability share to 80%, which was applied to firms with more than 800 employees. The linear schedule of liability components for firms with 50 to 800 employees was also adjusted accordingly. As a result, the costs of the unemployment tunnel increased substantially for large firms with more than 500 employees, while smaller firms enjoyed somewhat lower liabilities (Hakola and Uusitalo, 2005[10]). The reform is estimated to have reduced the risk of unemployment among older workers by 16% (Hakola and Uusitalo, 2005[10]), most likely by restraining large employers from targeting older workers in collective dismissals (see below).
Box 2.5. Employers’ costs for former employees in the unemployment tunnel or on disability benefit
The liability component in the unemployment tunnel
Employers have to pay at least part of the benefit costs (the liability component) when their former employee receives extended unemployment benefits (unemployment tunnel). This concerns employers with a payroll of over € 2 086 500 in 2019. The share of the liability component in total benefit costs rises progressively with the size of payroll and reaches 90% of costs for payrolls above € 33 384 000 (80% in case the unemployed was born between 1950 and 1956). The employer is not obliged to pay the liability component if employment was terminated before the employee reached the age of 56, or the employee resigned on their own initiative. However the latter does not apply to the cases where employees agreed to leave voluntarily with a compensation package from their employer.
Employers may also be obliged to pay part of unemployment benefits if: (1) their former employees have become entitled to the unemployment benefits due to the termination of their employment after reaching the age of 60; (2) they are still receiving unemployment benefits after the reaching the minimum eligibility age for old-age pension; or (3) they started to receive unemployment benefit after reaching 62 and continued to receive an unemployment allowance until retirement on an old-age pension.
Experience-rating in disability benefits
Finland finances a major part of disability benefit through partially experience-rated premia, which are a weighted sum of the base premium rate and experience-rated premia. Experience-rating applies to firms with payroll exceeding the threshold of about EUR 2 million. Firms are classified into 11 contribution categories according to the number of disability pension incidences in the company over the past two years. Depending on these categories, a firm can earn a 90% discount on the base premium or be obliged to pay a 450% surcharge on top of the base premium (Kyyrä and Paukkeri, 2018[6]).
The age distribution of the employees in a firm does not affect its classification in contribution categories, since its past disability pension incidences are compared separately with the average disability rate for each age cohort, which creates an incentive for cream skimming in recruitment.
Source: Employment Fund homepage, Finnish Centre for Pensions homepage, (Kyyrä and Paukkeri, 2018[6]).
The 2005 and 2017 old-age pension reforms
The 2005 old-age pension reform introduced the life expectancy coefficient, which was applied for the first time in 2010. It reduces pensions for each cohort born after 1947 such that growing life expectancy does not increase the present value of pensions at age 62 from the level in 2009. The reform also changed the income base for calculating pensions from the last 10 years of each employment contract prior to retirement to incomes over the entire work history. This reform also introduced a flexible retirement age from 63 to 68 years, which turned out to have the opposite effect on extending working lives to the other measures. Before the implementation of a flexible retirement age in 2005, the full retirement age was 65 years. There was also an early retirement regime for retirees aged 60 to 64 years. Gruber et al. (2019[11]) find that the introduction of a flexible retirement age was effectively treated as lowering the full retirement age to 63 years. They find that retirement probabilities in the age range that was suddenly eligible for flexible retirement increased by 40% or more in 2005 from levels in 2004 despite only a modest increase in incentives to retire before age 65.
The 2017 pension reform raises the minimum retirement age gradually from 63 to 65 by 2025 and will link the minimum retirement age to life expectancy from 2030 onwards in such a way that the share of adult life spent in retirement remains constant. The reform also increases incentives to defer taking the pension (or part thereof) beyond the minimum age (by up to five years) by increasing pensions by 0.4% per month of deferral, which together with the 1.5% pension accrual rate results in a greater increase in pensions from working beyond the minimum eligibility age than before (when there was simply a 4.5% accrual rate). The 0.4% per month increment is actuarially neutral – on average, the present value of acquired pension rights is not affected by the timing of retirement.
To help people make more informed decisions about the timing of their retirement, a target retirement age for each cohort is calculated that corresponds to the age at which the pension increment from delaying retirement offsets the reduction from the life expectancy coefficient (Figure 2.8). For example, the minimum retirement age for those born in 1957 is 63 years and 9 months. For the increment for retirement beyond the minimum age to equal or surpass the reducing effect of the life expectancy coefficient for this cohort, they need to postpone their retirement by 12 months. It follows that the target retirement age for those born in 1957 is 64 years and 9 months.
The 2017 reform is estimated to increase the expected effective retirement age (Finnish Centre for Pensions measure, described above) in 2030 from 62.0 years under the previous legislation to 62.9 (Figure 2.9) (Reipas and Sankala, 2015[12]). By 2080, the expected effective retirement age is 64.7 years in the reform projection, compared with 62.8 years in the projection based on the previous legislation. Reipas and Sankala estimate that the reform (including the effect of raising the minimum age for extended unemployment benefit) will increase employment by around 53 000 by 2040, rising to 91 000 by 2080. The reduction in the number of retirees will also partly be channelled into unemployment, which is expected to rise by 14 000 by 2040 and 49 000 by 2080. The authors estimate that in the long run, the reform will raise the employment rate of 15-74 year olds by around two percentage points.
Pension expenditure relative to wages insured (i.e., the pension expenditure ratio) is estimated to be lower for decades to come under the current legislation than under the previous legislation (Reipas and Sankala, 2015[12]). Over 2030-50, this difference is estimated to be about 2% of GDP per year. Both the reduction in pension expenditure and growth in the wage sum are mainly attributable to later retirement. The reduction in the pension expenditure ratio means that the contribution rates needed to finance pensions are lower over coming decades than under the previous legislation. The reform sets the contribution rate at 24.4%, a relatively high level compared with many OECD countries, including Scandinavian Nordics, until the end of the 2060s. Assets under the Employee Pensions Act (to help pay for future pensions) are set to rise markedly, from 240% of the wage bill currently to 290% in 2080 whereas under the previous legislation they were projected to decline to 220% in 2080 (Reipas and Sankala, 2015[12]). The outlook will be less favourable, however, when Statistics Finland’s updated long-term demographic projections that take into account the large recent decline in the fertility rate are integrated (Box 2.6).
Box 2.6. Financing old-age pensions
Finland’s pension system is financed from both assets accumulated in pension funds (i.e., pre-funding) and pay-as-you-go (PAYG) pension contributions, with the latter source being the largest – only about one-fifth of private sector pension expenditure is financed by pension funds. The national pension and the guarantee pension, which are not earnings related, are solely funded by PAYG.
The Finnish Centre for Pensions projects an increase in total statutory pension expenditure from 13.4% of GDP in 2017 to 15% by 2085, with all of the increase occurring in the second half of the century owing to a shrinking working-age population (Tikanmäki et al., 2019[13]). The contribution rate under the Employees Pensions Act (TyEL contribution) is projected to rise from 24.3% in 2017 to 25% by the end of the 2020s and begin to increase rapidly in the 2050s owing to the decline in working-age population, reaching 30% in 2085. At this time, the contribution rate will be at a sustainable level. A constant TyEL contribution rate of 26.7% would be sufficient to finance expenditures in the long term. Contribution rates for municipal pensions in 2017 (28.5%) were slightly greater than the constant contribution rate sufficient to finance these pensions in the long term. Taking all earnings-related pension schemes together, the contribution rate in 2017 (29.2%) was sufficient to finance pension expenditure in the long term.
The projections are highly sensitive to assumptions about the birth rate and investment returns. A fertility rate of 1.20 instead of the 1.45 assumed in the projection would require the contribution rate in 2085 to be 4 percentage points higher than the baseline (the fertility rate was 1.41 in 2018). Should the annual real investment return be one percentage point lower than assumed (2.5% during 2019-28 and 3.5% thereafter), pension contributions would need to be raised to 33.3% by 2085 (3.2 percentage points higher than in the baseline scenario).
Source: (Tikanmäki et al., 2019[13])
Boosting activation
The requirement to look for jobs or to participate in training programmes attached to unemployment benefits is lenient, especially for old recipients (see below), resulting in long unemployment spells. The previous government tightened such conditions for benefit eligibility by requiring the newly unemployed to spend 18 hours in paid employment, earn at least EUR 241 in self-employment, or participate in five days of employment programmes at the employment office in their first three months of unemployment. Failure to meet any of these conditions resulted in a 4.65% reduction in the benefit level for 65 days. This activation model was repealed in January 2020, despite preliminary evidence that it could increase employment by 8 000, because some people were unable to fulfil the activation requirements owing to a shortage of training places. The government has proposed alternative measures to strengthen activation in the Employment Package for the 2021 Budget negotiation, including a new obligation for unemployed jobseekers to apply for up to four job opportunities every month and increased resources for the PES (Box 2.2). On the other hand, the Package reduces the strictness of unemployment benefit sanctions, including by giving a warning before imposing sanctions.
Reducing effective tax rates on labour income
As discussed in the 2018 OECD Economic Survey of Finland, work incentives in Finland are hampered by high average- and marginal effective tax rates on labour income. Part of the problem is tapering rules for unemployment benefits that include losing the benefit when working more than 80% of full-time. Furthermore, complex administrative procedures associated with various benefits discourage second earners from working more out of fear that they may end up losing some of them (Bureaucracy trap). While work incentives improved somewhat during the previous government’s term owing to a freeze on the indexation of social security benefits, this improvement has been reversed to some degree by the current government. The previous government commissioned a pilot study replacing means-tested benefits with a universal basic income that guarantees a given level of income regardless of employment status as an option to simplify the benefits system and to boost work incentives (Box 2.7). The study found that the basic income scheme did not lead to a significant increase in the employment rate but improved subjective well-being (Kangas et al., 2020[14]). There were, however, serious limitations to the experiment because some participants still had to claim means-tested benefits, there was a lack of diversity in types of labour market status, no account was taken of the increase in taxes that would be needed to finance such a scheme and forward-looking participants’ behaviour was affected by the knowledge that the scheme was only for a fixed term. Moreover, the findings may have been impacted by the introduction of the activation model in early-2018.
Box 2.7. The basic income experiment
The basic income experiment was designed and administered by the Ministry of Social Affairs and Health and the Social Insurance Institution (Kela). It provided an opportunity for long-term unemployed persons receiving the basic unemployment benefit to opt out of the existing benefit system and instead receive a basic non-means-tested income not subject to activation conditions, significantly lowering the tax wedge on labour income and administrative burdens. The experiment targeted individuals aged 25-58 who were receiving basic unemployment benefit from Kela in November 2016. Among them, 2 000 randomly selected individuals were paid € 560 per month regardless of whether they found a job or participated in activation measures.
These 2 000 individuals were compared with other individuals in the target group on their employment status, namely their working hours and earnings, as well as well-being, for the period from November 2017 to October 2018. It was found that the employment rate for basic income recipients improved slightly more during this period than for the control group. The basic income recipients were employed for 78 days on average, as opposed to 73 days for the control group. Overall, the recipients of basic income only marginally outperformed the control group in terms of the average number of working days, but did enjoy higher levels of subjective well-being. The experiment was, however, subject to serious shortcomings. For instance, individuals with an entitlement to unemployment benefit greater than the universal income, mainly because they had children, did not benefit from less bureaucracy and non-compulsory participation in active labour market programmes. Moreover, the long-term unemployed are unlikely to be skilled in job search and therefore may respond less to a lower labour tax wedge; the experiment should have been run with different types of labour market status. In addition, the impact of the basic income could have been larger had the activation model not been introduced in early-2018 (see above) as it may have boosted job search efforts of unemployment benefit recipients (the control group) more than of recipients of the basic income. On the other hand, the scheme was not revenue neutral. Allowing for the effect of higher taxes to pay for it would reduce any favourable effect that the scheme may have had on labour supply.
Source: (Kangas et al., 2020[14]).
The employment package announced in 2019 and revised in the proposed 2021 budget
To help attain the employment goal, the government announced an employment package in 2019, which featured an increase in resources for the public employment service (PES), more intense job counselling, reform and increased use of wage subsidies, and a plan to increase the activity rate and ultimately employment among the disabled and an increase in work-related immigration. These measures were subsequently incorporated in the employment package prepared for the 2021 Budget (Box 2.2).
The planned increase in resources for the PES is a positive step, given that Finland has relatively low PES staffing per unemployed person compared with other Nordic countries. Indeed, the number of unemployed per caseworker has more than doubled since 2008, putting the employment service under strain (OECD, 2018[15]). Against this background, the government plans to make job counselling more intense by recruiting more PES staff. Empirical studies point to the positive employment effect of more intense job counselling. For example, a pilot project in Germany found that a lower caseload per caseworker led to more re-employment and shorter unemployment durations (Hainmueller et al., 2016[16]). Similarly, a working-class area in the Helsinki region that implemented more intense counselling experienced a greater reduction in unemployment than other parts of Helsinki. However, only € 70 million over a four-year period has been budgeted for this reform, which is unlikely to be enough to implement it fully given that follow-up will require additional resources.
The government also intends to increase the use of wage subsidies for companies and public employers and a recruitment subsidy for micro-enterprises. An employer hiring an unemployed jobseeker can receive financial assistance in the form of a pay subsidy that covers up to 30, 40, 50 or 100% of wage costs. Total wage subsidies will cost EUR 10-15k on average per year per person-employee. The government estimates that this wage subsidy reform will give work to 500-1 000 jobless people in the long run by increasing incentives for firms to hire them. To encourage take-up of wage subsidies by employers, the government also plans to reduce bureaucracy, given that it has been administratively complex to hire someone with the current scheme. The effects of the wage subsidy scheme on employment may be severely reduced by deadweight losses – many beneficiaries might have found jobs without subsidisation. Empirical results suggest that the effectiveness of wage subsidies in Finland has been rather weak – wage subsidies applied in the private sector generate small positive effects, whereas those applied in the public sector do not (Asplund et al., 2018[17]). The absence of positive effects of wage subsidies in the public sector, which comprise around 30% of total wage subsidies, is not surprising as their aim is to reduce the burden of labour market subsidy (i.e., social assistance for the unemployed who do not qualify for unemployment allowance) on municipal finances and to push the older unemployed to the unemployment tunnel. Finding ways to reduce deadweight effects and to increase permanent employability is important if these programmes are to be retained.
The government has also planned further reforms to promote employment among those in need of special support, including the disabled. A programme for work and welfare and a working capacity programme for people with partial work capacity is in the pipeline. As part of the programme, a condition will be added to public procurement contracts that will incentivise the employment of persons with partial working capacity and others with a vulnerable labour market status. The careers of 18 800 persons were cut short by entry into disability pension in 2016, and 600 000 Finns estimate that disability or disease affects their work and opportunities for finding employment. To lengthen careers and to prevent further losses in labour input, the employer, staff and occupational health care will collaborate in taking measures that promote workability and return to work.
Overall, the net effect of the original 2019 employment package would have fallen short of the government’s employment objective as it did not focus on increasing employment of older workers, even though this group has the greatest untapped potential. It is therefore welcome that the employment package for the 2021 budget negotiation emphasises boosting employment of older workers (Box 2.2). To increase their employment rate, it is essential that the package include measures to tighten further pathways to early retirement.
Increasing the employment of older workers
Early retirement pathways reduce employment of seniors
The main reason that the employment rate of older workers is lower in Finland than in the Scandinavian Nordics is that Finns have better access to early retirement pathways, notably through unemployment or disability benefits. In 2017, about 12% and 14% of new pensioners aged 63 were previously receiving unemployment or disability benefits, respectively, for several years, according to the Finance Ministry.
These institutional arrangements are motivated by a concern that older workers who lose their job may have greater difficulty than others in finding another suitable job, exposing them to the risk of a sharp drop in income before retirement. However, such arrangements may also increase the risk of older workers being targeted in lay-offs because they have replacement incomes for the rest of their lives and are less harmed by worse income prospects (‘scarring’) following a period of unemployment than other workers. Laying-off workers is relatively easy in Finland despite relatively strict employment protection legislation (EPL) for individual and collective dismissals(Figure 2.10), because it tends not to be binding in practice as employers and employees often negotiate voluntary departures with compensation packages (OECD, 2016[18]). The conditions for making temporary lay-offs under the short-term work scheme are particularly lenient relative to those in other OECD countries (OECD, 2016[18]): worker consent is not required, laid-off workers receive regular unemployment benefits and employers do not bear any financial costs except when the laid-off workers enter the unemployment tunnel. Older workers laid-off under this scheme are less likely to be hired back than other workers. The conditions for using this scheme should be reviewed to ensure that it is not providing a low-cost route for employers to make permanent lay-offs of older workers.
Phase out the unemployment benefit route to early retirement
The unemployment early retirement pathway starts with a spell on unemployment benefit, which may be up to 500 weekdays for a person aged 58 or more when they became unemployed (see Box 2.4). If they are still receiving unemployment benefit when they turn 61 (62 for people born in 1961 or later) and have worked for at least five of the past 20 years, they are entitled to extended unemployment benefit (unemployment tunnel) until they reach 65. Thus, it is possible to draw unemployment benefits continuously from age 59 (60 from 2023) until 65 without re-charging benefit rights. The unemployment pathway to retirement can be entered even younger by re-charging unemployment benefit rights close to expiry before reaching the qualifying age for extended unemployment benefit. For the unemployed whose benefits are due to expire after 57 years of age, this can be done by taking up their entitlement to participate in activation measures or to a job with the local municipality. For persons already aged 60, the maximum duration of earnings-related unemployment benefits (until 65) is only matched in Belgium among OECD countries (Figure 2.11). This duration is much longer than in the Scandinavian Nordics, where the extension of unemployment benefits for older workers was abolished years ago (OECD, 2018[19]), thereby curbing the use of unemployment benefits as a pathway to early retirement (OECD, 2013[20]).
The effect of these arrangements on unemployment rates for older workers can be seen in the sharp increase in rates in the run-up to the age threshold for extended unemployment benefit (Figure 2.12). Prior to the age at which the unemployment pathway to retirement begins (currently, 59), unemployment rates for the over 50s are similar across ages, albeit at higher levels after the Global Financial Crisis than immediately before. In 2017, for example, the unemployment rate was around 10% from age 52 to 57. At age 58, when people becoming unemployed are entitled to an extra 100 days of benefit, the unemployment rate starts to rise and increases sharply to a peak of 16% at age 61, when unemployed people become entitled to extended unemployment benefit. The unemployment rate stays high at age 62 but falls sharply at age 63, which was the minimum eligibility age for old-age pension in 2017. Increases in the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit in successive reforms (from 57 to 59 years in 2005 (taking effect in 2009), to 60 years in 2012 (taking effect in 2015) and to 61 years in 2015 (taking effect in 2018)) have shifted the increase in unemployment to older ages. The eligibility age for extended unemployment is to rise further to 62 years, with effect from 2023.
Extended unemployment benefit substantially increases the odds of older workers becoming unemployed and reduces the odds of them becoming employed again. Exit from paid employment to unemployment begins prior to the qualifying age for extended unemployment benefit and increases sharply at ages within 500 weekdays of the qualifying age (Figure 2.13, Panel A). The spike in layoffs at the age when unemployment benefits can last until retirement (i.e., 500 working days before the qualifying age for extended unemployment benefit) (Panel B) points to the mutual interest of employers and employees in using the unemployment route to retirement – employers are able to reduce staffing in a socially acceptable way and, at the same time, reduce employment of workers who are often less profitable than others and employees get to retire early. Re-employment hazard rates plunge once the older unemployed reach the age at which they qualify for unemployment benefits until retirement, highlighting the lack of incentives for the older unemployed to find work again (Panel C).
In order to get the unemployed back into employment, unemployment benefits need to be combined with effective active labour market policies. However, in Finland activation measures push the older unemployed towards the unemployment tunnel rather than towards re-employment, as noted above. Indeed, the participation in activation measures by individuals not eligible for extended unemployment benefit surges a year before the eligibility age, while it drops considerably for those eligible for the tunnel (Figure 2.14).
The activation of individuals who entered the unemployment tunnel is very lenient. The PES offices usually do not devote as much attention to these individuals as to other groups (Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment, and Ministry of Social Affairs and Health, 2019[21]), as they are regarded as retired rather than unemployed. Should the PES enforce job search and work requirements more strictly, these older unemployed could switch from unemployment- to disability benefits rather easily (see below).
A major step to restrict access to early retirement routes would be to phase out the extension of unemployment benefits by gradually raising the eligibility age to the maximum age of entitlement (65) by 2029 and then abolish it at this point . Such a reform would remove the strong disincentive to work longer, as seen in the past each time the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit was increased; for instance, the 2005 reform that raised the eligibility age from 57 to 59 years increased the average age of the employed aged between 54 and 63 years by 7 months (Kyyrä and Pesola, 2020[22]). Older workers would be less willing to accept redundancy arrangements with their employers and, should they become unemployed, would have stronger incentives to search for a job and accept one; for instance, the 1997 reform that increased the eligibility age by two years doubled the probability of re-employment for the affected unemployed (Kyyrä and Wilke, 2007[23]). The PES would no longer be justified in not offering active labour market programmes to the older unemployed on the grounds that their financial security is assured without working. Moreover, increased employment hazard rates for older unemployed persons would boost the return on PES activation investments for unemployed seniors.
Eliminating the unemployment tunnel would encourage employers to hire and train older workers, as longer working lives would increase the period over which the fixed costs associated with hiring and training could be amortised (Saint-Paul, 2009[24]). Indeed, the past reforms that raised the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit boosted hiring of workers who were slightly younger than the cohort directly affected by the reforms, reflecting employers’ expectation that these workers would remain in work longer (Ilmakunnas and Ilmakunnas, 2015[25]).
Such a move would also reduce the costs of hiring older workers. Employers above a certain payroll size are responsible for a share of extended unemployment benefit costs of former employees who enter the unemployment tunnel after being laid off (see Box 2.5). While the liability component is intended to curb abuse of the unemployment tunnel by employers, it also creates strong disincentives for employers subject to this liability to hire workers in their late fifties. Abolishing the extended unemployment benefit would remove such disincentives.
If the unemployment tunnel is not eventually eliminated, reforms to restrict its use are needed. The recently legislated increase in the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit from 61 to 62 years from 2023 is a step in the right direction. Nevertheless, this age would also need to be linked to life expectancy beyond 2030 to prevent the maximum duration of extended unemployment benefit from rising.
Another reform to increase the employment rate of seniors would be to subject the older unemployed to the same activation and job search requirements in practice as other unemployed. Similarly, the unemployed should no longer be allowed to recharge their unemployment entitlements by participating in activation measures. Since participation in activation measures is a requirement for receiving unemployment benefits, rewarding such entitlement sends an undesirable signal that it is optional (OECD, 2016[18]). This entitlement also allows the unemployed, particularly the old unemployed, to chain unemployment benefits by participating in activation measures whenever current entitlement runs out.
In Finland, earnings-related pension entitlements accrue for individuals receiving earnings-related unemployment benefits, except when individuals are receiving extended unemployment benefit beyond the minimum retirement age. To increase incentives to work, the government should extend the non-accrual of pension rights to the whole period of extended unemployment benefit receipt. This would act as a tax on pensions from remaining unemployed, which is effective in motivating workers close to retirement to return to employment while maintaining an adequate level of unemployment benefits (Hairault et al., 2012[26]).
In order to discourage the dismissal of older workers through the unemployment tunnel, the government could consider extending the coverage of the liability component to a wider range of employers. The current payroll threshold for the liability component is about EUR 2.1 million (Box 2.5). As median annual earnings in the private sector were about EUR 38 000 in 2018, this level implies that most firms with less than 50 employees are exempt from the liability component. These firms have been exempted from the liability component and experience-rating out of concern that such costs could imperil their survival. However, such firms comprise 98% of firms in Finland and employ 46% of employees (European Commission, 2019[27]). As discussed above, past reforms that enlarged the coverage of experience-rating reduced risks of unemployment and inflows into disability benefit. The government should thus consider extending the liability component to small firms, if not micro firms. Lowering the threshold would also remove the disincentive for firms just below the threshold (i.e. firms with 49 employees) to grow into medium- to large-sized firms.
Align conditions for obtaining disability benefit for older workers with those for other workers
Disability benefits have been widely used as a pathway to early retirement in Finland. In 2017, about 20% of new pensioners aged 63 were previously receiving disability benefits, while 14% were receiving them since the age of 56. The probability of inflow into disability benefits soars when individuals turn 60 (Figure 2.15), the age when more lenient eligibility criteria for disability benefits, including non-medical factors, start to apply (Box 2.8). Disability benefit applicants aged 60 and over are rarely rejected (Figure 2.16). Furthermore, disability benefit recipients aged 60 and over are also much less likely to be rehabilitated, and therefore receive disability pension until retirement (Ministry of Finance, 2019[28]). This is both because older workers can refuse rehabilitation measures and because existing rehabilitation measures are not effective in restoring older workers’ work capacity (Aho et al., 2018[29]).
Inflow into disability benefits often surges when access to other early retirement pathways is tightened by policy changes. For instance, applications for a disability pension soared in 2018, when the activation model came into force, because unemployed jobseekers were not subject to benefit sanctions for not fulfilling activation requirements if they had a pending disability benefit application (Laaksonen, Rantala and Salonen, 2019[30]). Disability benefits may also be used by employers as an alternative measure to let go of older workers when collective dismissal is harder to justify. Indeed, employees working for firms with high worker turnover are more likely to flow into sickness and disability benefits (Korkeamäki and Kyyrä, 2012[5]).
Disability benefits are claimed after workers have been on sickness leave for a year, during which they claim sickness benefits from the Social Security Institution, Kela (Box 2.8). Overall, the health status of older workers has improved markedly in recent years owing to more healthy lifestyles (less smoking and alcohol consumption), reducing the number sickness benefit claimants (Figures 2.17 and 2.18).
By reducing the incidence of disability benefit awards to older workers and hence employers’ experience-rated disability benefit contributions, excluding non-medical criteria from disability benefit assessments would also reduce the cost of hiring older workers. Finland is one of few countries that use experience-rating in disability insurance contributions to incentivise employers to take preventive workplace measures against disability. Employers with payroll exceeding EUR 2 million must pay higher contributions when their employees claim disability benefits (see Box 2.5). Such employers consider the risk of having to pay higher contributions as a barrier to hiring older workers (Liukko et al., 2017[7]).
Box 2.8. Sickness and disability benefits in Finland
Sickness benefit
Workers aged between 17 and 67 years can claim sickness allowance when they become ill and are unable to work. The sickness allowance is disbursed by the Social Security Institution (Kela) for a maximum of 300 working days and is earnings-related – the amount of benefit is calculated based on confirmed taxable earnings. Also, employers typically pay the full salary during the first one to three months of illness, depending on the collective agreement.
Disability benefits
After having received the sickness benefit for a period of about one year, workers assessed to be in further need of rehabilitation can apply for earnings-related disability benefits. Those assessed to have lost over 60% of working capacity are eligible to the full rehabilitation- or disability benefit, while those having lost 40% to 60% of working capacity are entitled to partial rehabilitation- or disability benefit. The amount of the rehabilitation benefit is the same as that of the disability benefit, and the partial benefit amounts to half of the full benefit.
Rehabilitation benefits are intended for recipients who are likely have their work capacity restored through rehabilitation and can be drawn during the fixed period specified in their rehabilitation plans. Those unlikely to return to work or whose capacity to work is not restored after rehabilitation receive disability benefit, which can be drawn until they reach the minimum retirement age for an earnings-related pension.
Disability benefit eligibility is assessed primarily on the basis of medical examinations that consider the claimant’s capacity to perform his/her original job or a different job. However, claimants over 60 are subject to more lenient eligibility criteria that include various non-medical factors like the length of employment history or working conditions. This special provision is a legacy of the Individual Early Retirement scheme that was abolished in 2002, which applied lenient medical criteria to disability benefit applicants aged 60 and over.
Earnings-related disability benefits are part of the earnings-related pension system. Those not eligible to an earnings-related benefit can claim a disability benefit in the national pension system until the age of 65 (the retirement age for the national pension).
Source: Finnish Centre for Pensions website, (European Commission, 2019[31]), (Kyyrä and Paukkeri, 2018[6]).
More needs to be done to curb the inflow from long-term unemployment into disability pension. In 2018, almost half of all new disability pension recipients were previously unemployed. While (long-term) unemployment is often due to reduced work capacity, unemployed people with a disability do not receive a rehabilitation assessment, in contrast to sickness benefit recipients, and therefore have little chance of restoring their work capacity. Furthermore, since healthcare services in Finland are often occupation linked, the unemployed receive less attention from the health care system, which results in health deterioration that reduces employability (von Werder and Thum, 2013[32]). Some municipalities provide free medical screening for anyone over 45 as well as rehabilitation plans for long-term unemployed but such services are not universal.
The rehabilitation system also need to be overhauled so that it works better to return people to employment. Some 80% of people who receive a positive rehabilitation assessment never begin a rehabilitation programme. There are several reasons for this outcome, including the lack of suitable rehabilitation programmes and/or support to find them and a strengthened ‘pension orientation’, whereby a person not yet receiving disability benefit refuses rehabilitation because she considers herself already to be a pensioner and, as such, sees no point in participating in rehabilitation programmes.
Non-medical criteria for assessing the work capacity of disability benefit applicants aged 60 or more should no longer be taken into account to limit the use of disability benefit as an alternative pathway to early retirement. Past experience in Finland and other Nordic countries suggests that such reform lengthens working lives significantly. For instance, Finland’s 2002 reforms that abolished the Individual Early Retirement scheme that allowed workers aged 60 years or more to access disability benefit under lenient medical criteria (see Box 2.8) reduced the probability of a worker retiring through disability benefit by age 63 by 25% and extended working lives by as much as 3.4 months (Kyyrä, 2015[4]). Likewise, Sweden experienced a significant drop in the disability hazard rate and an increase in the employment rate of individuals aged 60 to 64 following the 1997 reform that excluded non-medical criteria from assessments of disability benefit eligibility (Jönsson, Palme and Svensson, 2012[33]). As noted above, longer working lives would also encourage employers to hire and train older workers.
Enhancing current and future older workers’ skills
Reforms to close early retirement pathways need to be coupled with policies that enhance the employability of older workers and make the work environment more conducive to longer working lives. Steps need to be taken to increase the capability of workers to keep up with technological change, such as digitalisation, and to facilitate the smooth transition to new jobs by displaced older workers. Potential discrimination against older workers at work or with respect to job applications must also be tackled and more flexible working time arrangements should be promoted.
Labour market demand in Finland has been driven in recent decades by the fastest adoption of digital technologies among EU economies (European Commission, 2019[34]). Jobs have become more polarised, as the share of medium-skill production and clerical jobs has decreased while low-skill service occupations and high-skill specialist occupations have gained share (Pekkala Kerr, Maczuskij and Maliranta, 2016[35]). While the polarisation of labour markets is commonly observed across OECD countries, the decrease in the share of mid-skill jobs in employment in Finland has been mostly offset by the increase in the share of high-skill jobs (Figure 2.19). The strong demand for high-skilled workers reflects the fact that jobs in Finland are more intensive in non-routine tasks and ICT skills than those in other OECD countries (Figure 2.20). This job structure underlies the smaller share of jobs at high risk of automation than in most other OECD countries. Nevertheless, about one quarter of jobs are likely to undergo significant change, a share that is closer to the OECD average (Figure 2.21).
Given the particularly high demand for skills in Finland, older workers face severe challenges in the labour market as they have lower information processing skills, including literacy and numeracy skills, than the rest of the working-age population, particularly than the younger generation (Figure 2.22). This reflects both their lower education levels than younger cohorts and a deterioration of skills with age. The older age group surveyed in the 2012 PISA study did not benefit from the comprehensive school system implemented from 1972, which provided a nine-year basic education to everyone. Furthermore, Finland belongs to a group of countries where literacy skills erode somewhat with age (Barrett and Riddell, 2016[36]). The large inter-generational skill gaps combined with fast diffusion of digital technologies reduces the chance of older workers remaining employed, especially those facing higher risks of being replaced by computers or robots. Fortunately, the seniority wage premium is low in Finland, limiting the loss of cost competitiveness of older workers, making it easier for them to remain in continuous work (OECD, 2019[37]) (Figure 2.23).
The unemployment tunnel increases the probability of early retirement of older workers more in occupations that are highly exposed to digital technologies and automation risks than in other occupations (Box 2.9). Indeed, the surge in unemployment risks starting 500 days before the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit (documented in Figure 2.13, Panel A) is significantly larger for office clerks or production workers (Figure 2.24), occupations often characterised by high shares of codifiable routine tasks that are more likely to be automated (Nedelkoska and Quintini, 2018[38]). The interaction between the unemployment tunnel and digital technologies in driving older workers out of employment documented in Box 2.9 underscores the importance of closing pathways to early retirement, in addition to boosting skills, for ensuring the inclusion of older workers in the future of work.
Box 2.9. The unemployment tunnel promotes the early retirement of workers more exposed to digital technologies
Joint research with the VATT Institute for Economic Research explores the effect of the unemployment tunnel on the early retirement of older workers exposed to technological change (Yashiro et al., 2020[39]). In general, older workers facing radical technological change are induced to retire early, because it does not pay for them to invest in new skills that complement new technologies given their short remaining working lives (Ahituv and Zeira, 2011[40]). For the same reason, employers also have little incentive to train older workers instead of letting them go (Saint-Paul, 2009[24]). Availability of early retirement pathways should facilitate this technology-induced retirement. It is therefore expected that the unemployment tunnel increases the outflow from employment more for individuals with higher exposure to technological change.
Empirical strategy
The research exploits the rich FOLK employer-employee database, which makes it possible to track individuals’ transitions from employment to unemployment or inactivity and includes rich information on individuals’ socio-economic background and benefit entitlements. The dataset is matched with novel occupation-level indicators constructed from the OECD Survey of Adult Skills (PIAAC) that capture the exposure of workers to digital technologies, namely the risk of automation, the intensity of routine tasks and the intensity of ICT skills. Higher intensity of routine tasks suggests a higher risk of substitution of machines or computers for workers (Autor, Levy and Murnane, 2003[41]). Higher intensity of ICT skills is likely to lower risk of such substitution, as ICT skills complement machines and computers.
The probability of early retirement is defined as the probability of an individual i aged between 50 to 65 not being employed at the end of the period t conditional on being employed in the past two years. It is estimated as the following linear probability function:
The second term on the right-hand side is the occupation-level measure of exposure to digital technologies described above. Its coefficient captures the impact of a one standard deviation higher exposure to digital technologies than the average across occupations, for individuals who are not eligible for the unemployment tunnel. The third term is a dummy variable indicating the eligibility for the unemployment tunnel for individuals with an average level of exposure to digital technologies. It takes the value one two years before the eligibility age for extended unemployment benefit, to take into account the entitlement to 500 working days of unemployment benefit enjoyed by older individuals (see above). The interaction term (the fourth term) indicates the case of an individual with higher than the average exposure to digital technologies and access to the unemployment tunnel. Its coefficient is expected to be positive and significant, except when is the intensity of ICT skills, in which case it is expected to be negative. is a vector of control variables that includes age, gender, educational attainment, marital status, the area of residence, sector, and also year dummies intended to capture fluctuations in labour demand.
Empirical findings
The main findings (Table 2.2) confirm the above hypotheses:
Higher exposure to digital technologies is associated with a higher risk of unemployment, but its impact is small when the individual is not eligible to the unemployment tunnel. For instance, an individual exposed to higher risks of automation would face a 0.9 percentage point higher probability of exiting employment each year. Higher intensity of routine tasks also seems to increase this probability but the impact is not statistically significant. On the other hand higher intensity of ICT skills decreases early retirement risks.
The impact of digital technologies is considerably larger when an individual is eligible to the unemployment tunnel. A one standard deviation higher risk of automation increases the unemployment risk by 1.3 percentage points every year. Intensity of routine tasks or ICT skills also significantly affect the unemployment risk.
Eligibility to the unemployment tunnel by itself increases the unemployment risk substantially, as documented in previous studies. An individual exposed to an average level of automation risk would face a 1.8 percentage point higher risk of unemployment by gaining eligibility for the unemployment tunnel.
The combined impact of digital technologies and the unemployment tunnel amounts to a 4 percentage-point higher risk of unemployment compared with an individual exposed to an average level of automation risk who is not eligible for the unemployment tunnel. This is equivalent to an 80% increase in the risk of unemployment for an individual aged 57-58.
Table 2.2. Estimated coefficients on digital technologies and the unemployment tunnel
Dependent variable: Probability of early retirement |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Variable of exposure to digital technologies |
Risk of automation |
Intensity in routine task |
Intensity in ICT skills |
Exposure to digital technologies (Techi) |
0.887*** |
0.134 |
-0.789*** |
Eligibility to the unemployment tunnel (UTit) |
1.757*** |
1.974*** |
1.952*** |
The interaction (Techi×UTit) |
1.336*** |
1.670*** |
-1.126*** |
Note: The sample covers workers aged 50 to 65 in the private sector. All coefficients are multiplied by 100 so that they can be interpreted as percentage points. The number of worker-year observations for each model is 3,119,580. Standard errors are clustered at the individual level. *** indicates statistical significance at 1% level.
Source: (Yashiro et al., 2020[39])
Simulating the impact of unemployment tunnel reforms on the employment of older workers
A model similar to the one above can be used to simulate the impact of reforms that tighten access to the unemployment tunnel on employment of older workers. Figure 2.25 shows that the probability that an individual employed at age 49 remains employed declines more steeply with age, if he is exposed to a higher than average risk of automation (corresponding to the red lines). Reforms to tighten access to the unemployment tunnel, which correspond to a shift from dotted lines to the solid line, increase the probability of continuous employment significantly for individuals exposed to higher automation risks but have little impact on those exposed to lower risks of automation.
Maintaining employability at older ages through more targeted lifelong learning
The fast pace of digitalisation in Finland means that on-the-job training and lifelong learning opportunities are particularly important for workers to maintain their employability at older ages by updating their skills throughout their working lives. The participation rate in adult education in Finland is among the highest in the OECD, thanks partly to the Adult Education Allowance that provides income replacement for up to 15 months to engage in lifelong learning. However, there are large gaps in participation rates between older- and young workers or low-skilled and other workers (Figure 2.26), even though older workers and unskilled workers participate more in adult education in Finland than in many other OECD countries. Furthermore, employees in occupations characterised by declining employment, who are likely to have been replaced by computers or robots, participate only modestly in adult education, especially if they are older or less-skilled (Asplund, Kauhanen and Vanhala, 2019[42]). Lower participation by the unskilled in adult education is a challenge, given that they are the ones particularly prone to automation risks (Nedelkoska and Quintini, 2018[38]).
While Finland’s adult education is well developed and accessible in terms of low financial costs and high flexibility, programmes are not targeted to specific population groups, except some aimed at integrating immigrants (OECD, 2020[43]). Adult education courses targeted at unskilled workers should be put in place to increase their employability at latter stages of their working lives. In particular, adult education courses that rebuild digital and other basic skills that form the foundation for further continued learning are important for helping lower-skilled workers adapt to digitalisation. Some projects funded by the European Social Fund aim to improve foundation skills and basic education for adults. For example, the Skills in the Digital Age project launched in 2018 provides training in basic digital skills. The government plans to implement further measures to train adults with low basic skills. Engaging unskilled workers in training and learning requires rigorous outreach efforts, strong counselling services, as well as innovative approaches (Box 2.10). Indeed, the government envisages introducing lifelong guidance in continuous learning, especially for older and unskilled workers. These efforts are to be complemented by ongoing initiatives to boost the overall educational attainment of Finnish workers, as 16% of Finnish workers lack upper-secondary educational attainment. The government plans to increase the minimum school leaving age from 16 to 18 and a pilot study is underway extending free pre-primary education from one year to two.
Finland needs to increase training programmes that are more work relevant and result in skills recognition. In contrast to other European countries, adult education in Finland is biased toward formal education such as Bachelor’s degree programmes at universities (OECD, 2020[43]). As formal education is free of charge and involves financial support, workers with tertiary educational attainment seeking to acquire additional qualifications often pursue university degrees. For example, 45% of new starters in Bachelor’s degree programmes already hold bachelor’s degrees (OECD, 2020[43]). However, individuals with low educational attainment have little interest in pursuing university degree programmes, which require substantial time commitment (three to four years of full-time study) and are less aligned to labour market needs than vocational training organised by employers. Another undesirable effect of many adults pursuing continuous education at universities is that they crowd out study places for younger generations seeking to enter tertiary education. This contributes to Finland’s exceptionally late completion of tertiary education. A 2018 reform obliged universities to offer continuing education by modules, which are shorter than degree programmes and may alleviate competition over study places. Yet, more can be done to increase shorter and more practical training that is more accessible for unskilled workers.
The role of employers in shaping the content of adult education needs to be strengthened, in order to increase the labour market relevance of adult education. Adult education in Finland is mostly designed and provided by public institutions, with employers only playing a consulting role (OECD, 2020[43]). The government has encouraged vocational education institutions and universities to strengthen labour market relevance by incorporating labour market performance of graduates in their funding system. For instance, 15% of the funding of vocational education and training schools reflects the labour market performance of their graduates. The government also subsidises employer-provided vocational training for employee upskilling (the Precise training scheme). Yet, there is still room for further collaboration between the government and employers, namely in designing curricula and recognising skills acquired in non-formal education and training.
Low-skilled adults often face more complex obstacles to participation in adult learning than their higher skilled counterparts, including having greater household obligations and tighter financial constraints (OECD, 2019[44]). They therefore need more comprehensive advice and guidance services, not least because they have less access to relevant information on education and training opportunities as well as available financial assistance. Yet, career guidance opportunities for low skilled adults are somewhat limited in Finland until they become unemployed, at which point they have priority access to job counselling services at the PES (OECD, 2020[43]). The career guidance services can be strengthened through more intensive use of digital platforms such as online courses for career management or digitalised counselling services, as well as larger role by private providers. One particularly promising area of collaboration between the public sector and employers is assessment and validation of worker competencies in mid-career, which identifies skills that workers should acquire and provides necessary training. Such mid-career reviews are effective in ensuring the employability of unskilled workers at older ages (OECD, 2019[37]). However, employers often do not want to bear the full costs of mid-career reviews and associated training, as the skills acquired would mostly be transferable. Social partners should seek to reach consensus on their roles in financing this work-based adult education. Besides mid-career reviews, other means to support career planning of low-skilled adults could be: a) through enhancing their career management skills e.g., through digital courses; b) developing a variety of guidance and counselling services e.g., supporting private service providers or developing low-threshold one-stop guidance services for adults; and c) developing integrated digital services to support career planning.
Box 2.10. Training programmes targeted at low skilled workers in OECD countries
Reaching out to low-skilled workers
Active and direct outreach to low-skilled workers is essential for engaging them in learning. Outreach through the workplace can be particularly effective, as the workplace is one of the key places where individuals identify their training needs and take part in training opportunities. However, those who lack basic skills may not be able to communicate their training needs to employers, or employers may not be forthcoming in learning about such needs. In the United Kingdom, trade unions play a role in bridging employers and employees with low skills. For instance, the Unionlearn scheme supports workers in acquiring skills and qualifications to improve their employability. One of its key activities is the training of Union Learning Representatives (ULRs), who help workers identify their training needs and arrange learning opportunities within their companies. Since its inception in 2006, Unionlearn has trained more than 40 000 ULRs. It provides learning opportunities to about 250 000 workers per year, including disproportionally high numbers of workers with low qualification levels according to independent evaluations.
Holistic advice and guidance
Adults with low skills need support in identifying their training needs and in understanding which type of training is most appropriate for them. However, such comprehensive advice and guidance services require skilled caseworkers, who have sufficient time and resources to provide tailored assistance to each individual. In Iceland, Lifelong Learning Centres provide education and career counselling with a specific focus on low-skilled adults. Their guidance counsellors typically have a diploma or master’s degree in education and vocational counselling. There are dozens of Lifelong Learning Centres around the country including in sparsely populated areas, which conduct around 10 000 guidance counselling sessions with people with low qualification levels every year. In Austria, Bildungsberatung Österreich offers independent and free counselling for adults on education and training opportunities. The service specifically targets adults with disadvantages in the labour market, including the low-skilled, older adults, inactive adults and adults with a migrant background. Depending on the federal state, adults can choose from a range of modes to receive guidance, including face-to-face, on the phone or online via Skype or chat. The service is provided in 16 languages, although not all languages are spoken in every location.
Hands-on and innovative training approaches
Adult learning does not always equip low-skilled workers with the practical skills they need to succeed in the labour market. Furthermore, classroom-style adult learning may appeal little to low-skilled workers, as many of them have not experienced more than compulsory schooling. In Norway, the Skills Plus Work programme embeds basic skill training in the workplace. Since 2006, the programme supported more than 30 000 adults in acquiring reading, writing, numeracy and digital skills. Private and public enterprises can apply for grants for the training of their employees. Training must combine work and basic skill training and aim to strengthen workers’ motivation to learn. In Germany, a story-based learning project eVideoTransfer offers digital learning opportunities for workers with low basic skills and limited time. It develops industry-specific training, which combines learning content on basic skills and professional knowledge. All training is web-based and takes the learner through an engaging storyline, which is conveyed through videos. Users must have a basic level of digital literacy, although a learning module about how to use mouse and keyboard was developed to reach a wider target group.
Source: (OECD, 2019[44]).
Strengthening employment services to boost the re-employment of older workers
Phasing out the extended unemployment benefit would increase the demand for activation measures to promote the re-employment of displaced older workers. In 2017, Finland’s public expenditure on active labour market policies (ALMP) was about 1% of GDP, a share second only to Denmark and Sweden and twice the OECD average. About 45% of spending was on training, mostly provided by education institutions (OECD Employment Database) and delivered to younger people. The older unemployed participate much less in activation measures as they are either in the unemployment tunnel or expect to enter it. The activation rate of the unemployed aged 50 and over was only about 15% in 2015, less than half the rate for the younger unemployed (OECD, 2016[18]). Furthermore, the older unemployed who participated in activation measures were less likely to take part in training than the younger unemployed and more than half of the older unemployed benefited from rehabilitation measures or an employment subsidy, both of which have proven to be less effective in getting the unemployed back to work than training (OECD, 2016[18]); as noted above, private-sector employment subsidies have more favourable employment effects than public-sector subsidies, which serve to push the older unemployed into the unemployment tunnel. It is important to enrol older unemployed into more effective activation measures, namely training programmes targeted at older workers, in tandem with tightening activation requirements for receiving unemployment benefits.
The capacity of the PES needs to be strengthened to provide suitable activation measures to displaced older workers. In order to cope with the increased caseload with relatively low staffing (see above), the PES is increasingly relying on digital services to interact with jobseekers in counselling and monitoring job search. For instance, the initial registration as an unemployed jobseeker, which sorts jobseekers to the most appropriate service line, is almost always done online. The process of drawing up an employment plan together with the PES is also commonly done online. However, experience in Denmark shows that early and intensive face-to-face contact with the unemployed is very important for activating them (Maibom, Rosholm and Svarer, 2017[45]). Moreover, experience in Colombia shows that the PES is less effective in placing jobseekers in well-paying jobs when providing services online instead of face-to-face (Pignatti Morano, 2016[46]). Online services can work well for job-ready clients but not for older unemployed who need more comprehensive support and, in some cases, have difficulty using online services. Face-to-face counselling can be particularly important to assess the work capacity of older unemployed, which varies substantially. It is therefore welcome that in its Employment Package for the 2021 Budget negotiation the government has allocated additional resources for the PES to increase face-to-face counselling. Shifting some funding from relatively expensive activation programmes towards more and earlier face-to-face contact with a jobseeker, as well as automating back-office jobs rather than the counselling and monitoring processes, would further increase the effectiveness of the employment services. The government could also give private employment service providers a greater role as a way to increase the efficiency of employment services. Finland already outsources most of job search training to private providers, but could use them more extensively in job counselling and placement services. Evidence from some OECD countries suggests that extensive use of private providers helped the PES improve efficiency in job placement services, although an adequate incentive structure and rigorous performance assessment are key (Box 2.11).
There is a strong need for re-employment support adapted for older jobseekers at an early stage of their unemployment spell. Given the considerable difficulty they face in finding jobs once they are dismissed, early-stage intervention is key for avoiding long-term unemployment. In Finland, employment support is rarely provided before jobseekers register with the PES and there are no measures targeted towards older jobseekers. The Change training programme subsidised by the government provides vocational training for a minimum of 10 days for up to two years to dismissed workers. However, only a small portion of displaced workers who previously subscribed voluntarily to the Change security scheme are covered by this training (OECD, 2016[18]). Furthermore, while about a half of displaced workers enrolled in this training programme were re-employed after one year, the odds of re-employment were significantly lower for older workers with long tenure (Ålander et al., 2013[47]). The Competitiveness Pact agreed in 2016 introduced an obligation for employers with more than 30 employees to provide training to dismissed employees to help with their re-employment. This obligation ought to be extended in the renegotiation of the Pact in 2019-2020. More can be done by putting in place counselling services that prepare workers for new jobs as soon as they are notified of redundancy, as in Sweden, or by providing intensive re-training and guidance for older workers, like the Targeted Initiative for Older Workers programme in Canada.
Box 2.11. Bolstering employment services through extensive partnership with private providers: Australia and the United Kingdom
Australia and the United Kingdom are the two OECD countries where employment services were outsourced extensively to private providers, in order to maximise employment outcomes in a cost-effective way. Australia’s mainstream employment service has been entirely contracted out since the late-1990s to over a hundred for-profit and non-profit provider organisations competing in a “quasi-market”, with their operations financed mainly by service fees and placement and employment outcome payments. The United Kingdom introduced extensive quasi-market arrangements in employment services including those for long-term unemployed in 2011. The arrangements involved large contracts held by a few prime providers working with a network of sub-contractors and a black box approach where providers were free to offer any sort of service or set of interventions without mandatory requirements, to deliver predefined (longer-term) outcomes (OECD, 2014[48]).
In both cases, outcomes were somewhat disappointing initially and outcome-based payments were revised several times over the years to improve outcomes. In particular, both countries gradually strengthened payments for longer term employment outcomes and reduced payments for the initial intake of jobseekers. For example, in Australia, outcome payments are made when the placed jobseekers reach 13 weeks in employment and again when they reach 26 weeks. This motivated private providers to invest in capacity to achieve sustainable employment outcomes instead of placing jobseekers into any job. Both countries also extended the duration of service contracts to encourage long-term investment.
The Australian government regularly publishes Star Ratings of each private provider’s performance based on how many job placements and longer-term outcomes are achieved, while controlling for differences in jobseeker characteristics and local labour market conditions. In subsequent tender rounds, providers with low Star Ratings lose business, which is reallocated to higher performing providers and to some new market entrants (OECD, 2015[49]). In the United Kingdom, such rigorous measurement is not possible due to the lack of a comprehensive national database of jobseeker characteristics.
Overall, employment services in Australia and the United Kingdom are likely to have been delivered at a lower cost after extensive subcontracting to private providers. Employment outcomes also improved over time in both countries. In the United Kingdom, employment outcomes were satisfactory for average jobseekers but initially fell short of the authorities’ expectations for those who are harder to place in a job, especially those with reduced work capacity (National Audit Office, 2014[50]). There was evidence of providers providing little or no services to jobseekers who were perceived to be harder to place despite having received larger outcome payments for placing them. In response, the authorities strengthened oversight of contractors through a robust performance management regime that includes regular performance reviews based on monthly and yearly achievements. Programmes targeting harder to place groups were also introduced, such as the Specialist Employability Support introduced in 2015, focusing on helping those furthest away from the job market though an individually tailored combination of guidance, work placements, and work experience. With the exception of a subgroup of Employment and Support Allowance recipients, employment outcomes significantly outperformed the minimum levels expected by the authorities between 2013 and 2017 (Department of Work and Pension, 2020[51]).
Adapting the workplace to older workers
Work arrangements and the working environment should be reformed to promote longer working lives. In Finland, many workers retire early even though they could work longer not only owing to the availability of early retirement pathways but also because of an unattractive work environment for older workers. For instance, a survey reports that some 71% of surveyed workers who retired at the minimum retirement age of 63 or earlier could have worked longer had they wished to do so (Tuominen, 2013[52]). Their decision to retire instead was driven primarily by dissatisfaction with working conditions and a preference for leisure and hobbies, not by health conditions or family obligations. Examples of dissatisfaction with working conditions included time pressure at work, changes in work tasks, inflexible working hours, as well as poor administration and atmosphere at work. Such findings suggest that there is room to boost continued employment at older ages by improving the work environment for older workers, particularly through more flexible work arrangements, better training opportunities and a more accommodative mind-set towards older workers. Indeed, it has been found that high job satisfaction motivates older workers to work longer and is also associated with higher productivity (Böckerman and Ilmakunnas, 2017[53]).
More flexible work arrangements like part-time employment, flex-time or teleworking would allow not only older workers but also mothers with young children (see below) to work more. Potential demand for flexible work arrangements is high, as Finnish workers increasingly favour continuing to work while receiving old age pension (Tuominen, 2013[52]). Nevertheless, the share of part-time employment in employees aged 55-64 is about 16%, below Sweden (21%), Norway (23%) or the OECD average (20%), while the share of involuntary part-time employment is high (OECD Scoreboard on Older Workers). This suggests that there are insufficient part-time employment opportunities providing high work-life quality and income that compensates sufficiently for the loss of generous unemployment benefits. The government intends to develop adjusted unemployment benefits that would make part-time work pay. However, it is also necessary to improve the part-time working conditions. Part-time employment in Finland involves fewer opportunities for skills development, less work autonomy, and fewer possibilities for employees to set flexible working time compared to full-time employment (Ojala, Nätti and Kauhanen, 2015[54]).
Good working conditions not only help prevent work-related health problems and thus inflow into disability benefits, but also encourage older workers to work longer or return to work from disability. Overall, workers in Finland are less exposed to job strain, a situation where job demand exceeds available resources, than in most of OECD countries (Figure 2.27). However, the health outcomes of male workers with lower educational attainment in physically demanding occupations are considerably worse than for other workers, thereby shortening their working lives (von Werder and Thum, 2013[32]). Furthermore, the 2018 Quality of Work Life Survey finds a clear increase in the share of Finnish workers reporting symptoms of workplace hazards such as lack of sleep or feeling clear risks of severe burnout. Also, symptoms previously reported by old workers like neck, shoulder and back pain or feelings of fatigue are now common among young and middle age cohorts. These latest trends are alarming, as they may prevent current and future old cohorts from working longer.
Fighting age discrimination
Age discrimination is a major impediment for older workers to be hired or assigned to good jobs that motivate them to work longer. In Finland, the possibility of a vicious cycle between employers’ reluctance to hire and train older workers and older workers discouraged by such unfavourable treatment and not striving to remain employable was pointed out in Sterdyniak (2007[55]). A majority of corporate managers in Finland consider job applicants aged above 55 would be at a disadvantage against younger applicants with the same qualifications (Figure 2.28). In the 2013 Quality of Working Life Survey, about 9% of respondents report having observed discrimination towards aged people at their workplace, but nearly as many have also detected discrimination directed at young people (8%).
It is difficult to identify to what extent such unfavourable treatment of older workers is based on pure prejudice as opposed to economically rational reasons such as the generally-observed skills gaps between older- and younger workers (Figure 2.22) or specific costs associated with hiring older workers (see Box 2.5). The government will consider introducing the principle of anonymous job applications, in order to prevent age discrimination at the early stages of hiring. While this would prevent the discrimination against older applicants in the selection for interview, older workers are still likely to be discriminated against once their age is revealed at the interview (Neumark, 2020[56]). Fighting age discrimination requires broad efforts in changing employers’ behaviour. The government has launched several programmes involving social partners to improve the perception of continuous work at old age since the 1990s (OECD, 2018[57]). However, these efforts may have been undermined by early retirement pathways. The penalties against age discrimination should also be strengthened. In Finland, age discrimination is prohibited by the Constitution, the Non-Discrimination Act and the Employment Contract Act. Employers found guilty of discrimination without an important and justifiable reason may be subjected to a fine or imprisonment for a maximum of six months. However, claims based on age discrimination are rare, and are mostly presented alongside other claims, especially a groundless termination of an employment contract (Agediscrimination.info, 2018[58]).The government should strengthen its efforts to detect and prosecute age discrimination, especially in hiring and access to training.
Increasing the employment of mothers with young children
Financial working incentives are weak
The financial incentives to work are very weak for second earners with young children in Finland. For instance, a second earner earning 30% of the female earnings distribution with two children aged two and three faces a much higher participation tax rate than a person in the same situation but without children(Figure 2.29, Panels A and B). He or she loses 60% of the increase in gross income due to taxes and reduced benefits when moving from inactivity to full-time work (Panel B). Financial incentives to take up part-time work are also very weak compared with Sweden (Panel B). Given that second earners of young children are usually women, the financial incentives for Finnish mothers to work either full or part-time are weak compared with most OECD countries. Sweden, in contrast, provides strong financial incentives to both full-time and part-time work for second earners with children. When moving to full-time work, participation tax rates remain relatively low at below 30%, with or without children (Panels A and B). This results in smaller differences in labour participation between mothers and non-mothers and higher participation in both full- and part-time work.
Reducing the homecare allowance would improve work incentives
The strong disincentives to work for second earners with children is due to the generous social benefit granted for taking care of children at home instead of using ECEC services provided by municipalities. In Finland, the homecare allowance is paid for children up to three years old, immediately following the end of the 9-10 month parental allowance. The users are mostly women, although the scheme is in principle gender neutral (Figure 2.30). Although the generosity of the basic homecare allowance is comparable to similar schemes in other OECD countries (equivalent to roughly 10% of median earnings), there are various supplements (Sipilä, Repo and Rissanen, 2010[59]). For instance, there is a means-tested supplement, and a supplement for older siblings, when a mother has another child within a three-year period. Finland is the only country where the support is offered until age six via the sibling supplement (Hiilamo, Merikukka and Haataja, 2018[60]). Moreover, most of the large municipalities (including Helsinki, albeit only up until the youngest child is two years old) provide municipal supplements, partly to reward families for not using ECEC services that are more costly for municipalities to provide than homecare allowances (OECD, 2016[61]).The ECEC fee is relatively low, but the loss of generous homecare allowances results in the highest net cost of childcare in the Nordics (Figure 2.31).
Abolishing homecare allowances would considerably increase work incentives for mothers. The government has taken steps to improve work incentives for mothers: a flexible-care allowance was introduced in 2014 to improve incentives for part-time work for young or low-educated mothers with children under three years of age; and the ECEC fee was reduced by approximately 20% from 2017. Indeed, when working part-time, the participation tax rate dropped considerably (by around 30 percentage points) between 2015 and 2019 (Figure 2.32, Panel B). However, resolving the large incentive issues, especially for full-time work, will require removing or cutting back the homecare allowance (Panel A). According to simulations, the abolition of homecare allowances would profoundly transform work incentives for second-earner parents (Pareliussen, 2018[62]). However, it would likely have an adverse effect on public finances because the associated increases in expenditure on ECEC services and unemployment benefits for low-skilled mothers returning to the labour force would more than offset the savings on homecare allowances.
Reducing the homecare allowance would generate significant gains in terms of a more gender-equal working life. The homecare allowance contributes to reduced labour market attachment among mothers, as the majority of mothers choose to take care of their child at home on homecare allowance - 70% of all children under three were cared for at home with homecare allowance (Hiilamo, Merikukka and Haataja, 2018[60]). Long absences from the workforce among mothers undermine their career prospects and earnings mobility. This is because mothers miss crucial in-work transitions occurring in the early stages of careers, which promote stronger career advancement and income growth (OECD, 2018[63]). This is particularly true in Finland, one of the countries where in-work transitions have the greatest impact on income (Figure 2.33, Panel B). Finnish mothers with young children are 6.5 percentage points less likely to experience an in-work transition than their partner (Panel A). Indeed, gross earnings of women and men sharply diverge immediately after the birth of their first child, and do not converge fully later (Figure 2.34). Sieppi and Pehkonen (2019[64]) found that in the long run, having children reduces women’s earnings by about 25% compared with men, contributing to Finland’s large gender wage gap (see Chapter 1). Thus, reducing the homecare allowance will not only boost labour participation among mothers of young children but also reduce the gender wage gap.
The issue of homecare allowance is also the nexus of concerns about other important social issues. One issue is childbirth - if the homecare allowance has a positive impact on the fertility rate, reforming the homecare allowance may be seen as detrimental to childbirth. Indeed, Erlandsson (2017[65]) found that women using the homecare allowance tend to have a subsequent child sooner and more often than women not using the allowance. However, several evaluations suggest that policies aimed at helping women combine career and family have a greater positive effect on childbirth than financial subsidies. For instance, OECD (2011[66]) found that of all the policies introduced over the years, provision of good quality ECEC services appears to be the most effective in encouraging families to have children and women to remain in the workforce, rather than financial support trying directly to boost birth rates. Another issue is poverty - some households close to the poverty threshold might fall below the poverty line as a result of the abolition or significant reduction of the homecare allowance, which includes a means-tested element. This issue can be addressed by increasing existing alternative transfers which are not conditional on homecare, such as the basic parental leave amount. The introduction of new transfers also could be considered such as providing a means-tested supplement to the child benefit, or leaving child benefit unchanged, and instead providing a means-tested refundable tax credit to families with young children.
Enhancing access to childcare
Reduced homecare allowance, in turn, is likely to increase demand for early childhood education and care (ECEC). The participation rate of children in ECEC is currently lower than in other OECD countries on average (Figure 2.35). Only 30% of all children under three are in public ECEC due to the homecare allowance, which encourages mothers not to send their children to ECEC. This sets back children’s development, given that research provides growing and compelling evidence that ECEC makes a crucial difference to children’s future development and learning. During the first five years of their life, children learn at a faster rate than at any other time, developing their cognitive, social and emotional skills which make a crucial difference to their achievements throughout school and as adults (OECD, 2019[67]). Karhula et al. (2017[68]) also demonstrated positive educational effects for ECEC participation between ages one and three in Finland.
Consideration should be given to ensuring access to quality ECEC to cope with the likely increase in demand. If adequate childcare is unavailable, many mothers may abandon searching for a job. Indeed, some empirical studies find that lower accessibility of ECEC centres is significantly associated with a lower probability of employment among women with young children (Kawabata, 2014[69]). In Finland, some parents have reported that ECEC services were not sufficient to meet their needs (Figure 2.36). The main reasons are related to accessibility: places are not available, places are available but not nearby, or opening hours are not suitable. It will be important to ensure that those municipalities that do not provide sufficient places in convenient locations with suitable opening hours do so to help mothers get back into the labour force sooner.
Policy recommendations for realising the government’s objective of increasing employment
Main findings |
Recommendations (key recommendations in bold) |
---|---|
Increasing the employment of older workers |
|
Individuals receiving unemployment benefit at age 61 can have the benefit extended up to the statutory retirement age of 65. This encourages older workers to retire early, by first receiving the unemployment benefit for up to 500 workdays and then the extension (unemployment tunnel). |
Phase out extended unemployment benefit by progressively increasing the eligibility age to 65 by 2029, the maximum age for receiving the benefit, and then abolish it. |
The eligibility age for the unemployment tunnel is set independently of the minimum retirement age, which will lengthen the unemployment tunnel beyond 2030, when the minimum retirement age is linked to life expectancy, in the likely event that maximum age for extended unemployment benefit also increases. |
In the event that extended unemployment benefit is not phased out, link the eligibility age to the minimum eligibility age for old age pension from 2030 onwards |
Application of the activation requirement for the older unemployed, particularly those in the unemployment tunnel, is lenient. |
Apply activation requirements for the older unemployed with the same vigour as for other unemployed persons. |
The older unemployed approaching the end of their unemployment benefit entitlements have the right to a municipal job for long enough (usually six months) to recharge their unemployment benefit entitlements, enabling them to rotate between unemployment benefit and a municipal job until they reach retirement, either on extended unemployment benefit or, if it is abolished, on an old-age pension. These ‘jobs’ are financed by wage subsidies, which have been found to be ineffective in improving long-term employment outcomes |
Abolish public-sector wage subsidies. |
Earnings-related pension entitlements accrue for individuals receiving earnings-related unemployment benefits, except when individuals are receiving extended unemployment benefit beyond the minimum retirement age. |
Extend the non-accrual of pension rights to the whole period of extended unemployment benefit receipt, to enhance work incentives. |
The unemployment tunnel facilitates early retirement in particular of older workers who are more exposed to technological change than others. In general, older workers have lower information processing skills than the rest of the working-age population, reflecting not only their lower education levels but also deterioration of skills with age. |
Strengthen lifelong training targeted at unskilled workers. |
The probability of inflow into disability benefits increases when individuals turn 60, the age at which more lenient eligibility criteria for disability benefits, including non-medical factors, apply. |
Align the conditions for awarding disability benefit to persons aged 60 or over with those for other applicants, notably by no longer taking into consideration non-medical factors. |
Increasing employment for mothers of young children |
|
The generous homecare allowance discourages work by mothers with young children. Long absences from the labour force negatively affect their career prospects and earnings mobility, contributing to a large gender wage gap. |
Reduce the homecare allowance to increase incentives for mothers of young children to work. Compensate the income loss with alternative transfers that are not conditional on homecare. |
Early childhood education and care (ECEC) services are not sufficient to meet some parents’ needs in some municipalities, mainly due to a lack of convenient places available. |
Improve access to ECEC services by ensuring that those municipalities that do not provide sufficient places in convenient locations with suitable opening hours do so. |
References
[58] Agediscrimination.info (2018), Finland — age discrimination, http://www.agediscrimination.info/international-age-discrimination/finland.
[40] Ahituv, A. and J. Zeira (2011), “Technical Progress and Early Retirement”, Economic Journal, Vol. 121/551, pp. 171-193.
[29] Aho, S. et al. (2018), “Targeting of job-seeker services and the later employment of participants (in Finnish)”, Publication of the government’s analysis, assessment and research activities, No. 19/2018, Prime Minister’s Office, Helsinki.
[47] Ålander, T. et al. (2013), Security for change through cooperation - A study on the effectiveness and functionality of the operations model of Change security (in Finnish), Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment, Helsinki.
[17] Asplund, R. et al. (2018), The Impact of Wage Subsidies – An Evaluation of the Wage Subsidy System and Its Reforms, ETLA, Helsinki.
[42] Asplund, R., A. Kauhanen and P. Vanhala (2019), Workers in Declining Occupations: Modest Participation in Adult Education (in Finnish), Research Institute of the Finnish Economy (ETLA), Helsinki.
[41] Autor, D., F. Levy and R. Murnane (2003), “The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: an Empricial Exploration”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118/4, pp. 1279–1333.
[36] Barrett, G. and W. Riddell (2016), “Ageing and Literacy Skills: Evidence from IALS, ALL And PIAAC”, OECD Education Working Papers, No. 145, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[53] Böckerman, P. and P. Ilmakunnas (2017), “Do Good Working Conditions Make You Work Longer? Evidence on Retirement Decisions Using Linked Survey and Register Data”, Discussion Papers, No. 10964, IZA Institute of Labor Economics, Bonn.
[3] de la Maisonneuve, C. et al. (2014), “The Economic Consequences of Ageing: The Case of Finland”, Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1120, OECD, Paris.
[51] Department of Work and Pension (2020), Work Programme statistical summary: data to June 2020, https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/work-programme-statistical-summary-data-to-june-2020/work-programme-statistical-summary-data-to-june-2020.
[65] Erlandsson, A. (2017), “Child Home Care Allowance and the Transition to Second- and Third-Order Births in Finland”, Population Research and Policy Review, Vol. 36/4, pp. 607-630.
[27] European Commission (2019), 2019 SBA Fact Sheet Finland, European Commission, Brussels.
[34] European Commission (2019), Digital Economy and Society Index 2019 Country Report Finland, European Commission, Brussels.
[31] European Commission (2019), Your social security rights in Finland, European Commission, Brussels.
[2] Finland, S. (ed.) (2017), Finland/Sweden comparison: No great differences in working among mothers of small children, Tieto&Trendit, https://www.stat.fi/tietotrendit/artikkelit/2017/finlandsweden-comparison-no-great-differences-in-working-among-mothers-of-small-children/.
[11] Gruber, J. et al. (2019), “The Effect of Relabeling and Incentives on Retirement: Evidence from the Finnish Pension Reform in 2005 ⎢”, No. 328.
[16] Hainmueller, J. et al. (2016), “Do Lower Caseloads Improve the Performance of Public Employment Services? New Evidence from German Employment Offices”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 118/4, pp. 941-974.
[26] Hairault, J. et al. (2012), “Optimal unemployment insurance for older workers”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 96/5-6, pp. 509-519.
[10] Hakola, T. and R. Uusitalo (2005), “Not so voluntary retirement decisions? Evidence from a pension reform”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89/11-12, pp. 2121-2136.
[60] Hiilamo, H., M. Merikukka and A. Haataja (2018), “Long-Term Educational Outcomes of Child Care Arrangements in Finland”, SAGE Open, Vol. 8/2.
[25] Ilmakunnas, P. and S. Ilmakunnas (2015), “Hiring Older Employees: Do the Age Limits of Early Retirement and the Contribution Rates of Firms Matter?”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 117/1, pp. 164-194.
[33] Jönsson, L., M. Palme and I. Svensson (2012), “Disability Insurance, Population Health, and Employment in Sweden”, in Wise, D. (ed.), Disability Insurance, Population Health, and Employment in Sweden in Sweden, University of Chicago Press.
[14] Kangas, O. et al. (2020), “Evaluation of the Finnish Basic Income Experiment”, Reports and Memorandums of the Ministry of Social Affairs and Health, No. 2020:15, The Ministry of Social Affairs and Health, Helsinki.
[68] Karhula, A., J. Erola and E. Kilpi-Jakonen (2017), “Home sweet home? Long-term educational outcomes of childcare arrangements in Finland”, in Childcare, Early Education and Social Inequality: An International Perspective.
[69] Kawabata, M. (2014), “Childcare access and employment: The case of women with preschool-aged children in Tokyo”, Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies, Vol. 26/1, pp. 40-56.
[5] Korkeamäki, O. and T. Kyyrä (2012), “Institutional rules, labour demand and retirement through disability programme participation”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 25/2, pp. 439-468.
[4] Kyyrä, T. (2015), “Early Retirement Policy in the Presence of Competing Exit Pathways: Evidence from Pension Reforms in Finland”, Economica, Vol. 82/325, pp. 46-78.
[6] Kyyrä, T. and T. Paukkeri (2018), “Does experience rating reduce sickness and disability claims? Evidence from policy kinks”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 61, pp. 178-192.
[22] Kyyrä, T. and H. Pesola (2020), “Long-term effects of extended unemployment benefits for older workers”, Labour Economics, Vol. 62, p. 101777.
[9] Kyyrä, T., H. Pesola and A. Rissanen (2017), “Unemployment Insurance in Finland: A Review of Recent Changes and Empirical Evidence on Behavioral Responses”, SSRN Electronic Journal.
[23] Kyyrä, T. and R. Wilke (2007), “Reduction in the Long-Term Unemployment of the Elderly: A Success Story from Finland”, Source: Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 5/1, pp. 154-182.
[30] Laaksonen, M., J. Rantala and J. Salonen (2019), “Did the Activation Model for Unemployment Security affect applying for and receiving a disability pension?”, Finnish Labour Review, Vol. 62/4, pp. 17-27.
[7] Liukko, J. et al. (2017), “Effectiveness and incentive effects of experience rating in disability insurance: A questionnaire study on employers’ views”, Studies, No. 03/2017, Finnish Centre for Pension, Helsinki.
[45] Maibom, J., M. Rosholm and M. Svarer (2017), “Experimental Evidence on the Effects of Early Meetings and Activation”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 119/3, pp. 541-570.
[28] Ministry of Finance (2019), Ikääntyneiden työllisyyden edistämiskeinoja valmistelevan työryhmän loppuraportti, Ministry of Finance, Helsinki.
[21] Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Economic Affairs and Employment, and Ministry of Social Affairs and Health (2019), Explanation of supplementary day - care rights agreed in the pension reform and the effects of changes in the activation of the elderly, Ministry of Finance, Helsinki.
[50] National Audit Office (2014), The Work Programme, National Audit Office, London.
[38] Nedelkoska, L. and G. Quintini (2018), “Automation, skills use and training”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 202, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[56] Neumark, D. (2020), “Age Discrimination in Hiring: Evidence from Age-Blind vs Non-Age-Blind Hiring Procedure”, NBER Working Paper, No. 26623, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.
[43] OECD (2020), Continuous Learning in Working Life in Finland, Getting Skills Right, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[44] OECD (2019), Getting Skills Right: Engaging low-skilled adults in learning, http://www.oecd.org/employment/emp/%0Aengaging-low-skilled-adults-2019.pdf.
[67] OECD (2019), Providing Quality Early Childhood Education and Care: Results from the Starting Strong Survey 2018, TALIS, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[37] OECD (2019), Working Better With Age, Ageing and Employment Policies, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[70] OECD (2018), Good Jobs for All in a Changing World of Work: The OECD Jobs Strategy, OECD Publishing, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264308817-en.
[57] OECD (2018), Key policies to promote longer working lives in Finland.
[19] OECD (2018), Key Policies to Promote Longer Working Lives: Sweden Country note 2007 to 2017, OECD, https://www.oecd.org/els/emp/Sweden_Key%20policies_Final.pdf.
[15] OECD (2018), OECD Economic Surveys: FInland 2018, OECD Publishing.
[63] OECD (2018), OECD Employment Outlook 2018, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[18] OECD (2016), Back to Work: Finland: Improving the Re-employment Prospects of Displaced Workers, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[61] OECD (2016), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2016.
[1] OECD (2016), OECD Economic Surveys: Finland 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[49] OECD (2015), “Activation policies for more inclusive labour markets”, in OECD Employment Outlook 2015, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[48] OECD (2014), Connecting People with Jobs: Activation Policies in the United Kingdom, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[20] OECD (2013), Ageing and Employment Policies: Norway 2013: Working Better with Age, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[66] OECD (2011), Doing Better for Families, OECD Publishing, Paris.
[54] Ojala, S., J. Nätti and M. Kauhanen (2015), “Työn Laatu Ja Myöhempi Työura Osa- Ja Määräaikaisessa Työssä Työsuojelurahaston tutkimushanke 2013–2014”, Working papers, No. 90/2015, The Finnish Work Environment Fund, Helsinki.
[62] Pareliussen, J. (2018), “Basic income or a single tapering rule? Incentives, inclusiveness and affordability compared for the case of Finland”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 1464.
[35] Pekkala Kerr, S., T. Maczuskij and M. Maliranta (2016), “Within and Between Firm Trends in Job Polarization: Role of Globalization and Technology”, Working Paper, No. 308, Labour Institute for Economic Research, Helsinki.
[46] Pignatti Morano, C. (2016), “Do Public Employment Services improve employment outcomes? Evidence from Colombia”, Research Department working paper, No. 10, International Labour Office.
[12] Reipas, K. and M. Sankala (2015), Effects of the 2017 earnings-related pension reform, Finnish Centre for Pensions.
[24] Saint-Paul, G. (2009), “Does the Welfare State Make Older Workers Unemployable?”, IZA Discussion Paper, No. 4440, IZA.
[8] Shin, Y. and P. Böckerman (2020), Trade union-administered unemployment benefit and precarious workers in Finland, https://nordics.info/show/artikel/trade-union-administered-unemployment-benefit-and-precarious-workers-in-finland/ (accessed on 29 September 2020).
[64] Sieppi, A. and J. Pehkonen (2019), “Parenthood and gender inequality: Population-based evidence on the child penalty in Finland”, Economics Letters.
[59] Sipilä, J., K. Repo and T. Rissanen (2010), Cash-for-Childcare: The Consequences for Caring Mothers, Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.
[55] Sterdyniak, H. (2007), “Active Ageing Strategies to Strengthen Social Inclusion”, Working Paper, Science Po, Paris.
[13] Tikanmäki, H. et al. (2019), “Statutory pensions in Finland – long-term projections 2019”, Reports, No. 07/2019, Finnish Centre for Pensions, Helsinki.
[52] Tuominen, E. (2013), “Flexible retirement age in Finland The evaluation of the Finnish flexible retirement scheme in light of employer and employee surveys”, Working Paper, No. 03/2013, Finnish Centre for Pensions.
[32] von Werder, M. and A. Thum (2013), “Extending working life in Finland”, Working Document, No. 387, Centre for European Policy Studies, Brussels.
[39] Yashiro, N. et al. (2020), “Technological changes, labour market institutions and early retirement-Evidence from Finland”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper, Forthcoming.