Recent macroeconomic developments and short-term prospects
Monetary, financial and fiscal policies to promote stability and well-being
Addressing longer-run challenges to well-being
Greening growth requires mitigation of small particles emissions
OECD Economic Surveys: Hungary 2019
Key Policy Insights
Abstract
Key Policy Insights
The economy has grown strongly over the past five years. In 2017, growth exceeded 4% - a pace that the economy maintained in 2018 (Table 1). Initially, growth was driven by exports and then investments. As employment started to expand, the recovery has broadened to private consumption and housing investment; a development that is being reinforced by double-digit wage growth. Moreover, the economy is increasingly facing capacity constraints, leading to higher imports eroding the current account surplus.
Since the early 1990s, the main growth driver of the Hungarian economy has been foreign direct investments that have helped modernising production and supported the successful integration into global value chains. Nonetheless, income per capita remains low, but convergence towards OECD and EU average incomes has started to resume. Per capita GDP has reached two-thirds of the OECD average and slightly more in comparison with the EU average (Figure 1).
The high reliance on foreign direct investment to drive growth has led to a regionally unbalanced growth pattern. The western and central regions – the main recipients of foreign investment – and Budapest area with its large positive agglomeration effects have grown faster than the rest of the country. The left-behind regions are characterised by low employment, a high number of social transfer recipients and poor integration into regional and national supply chains.
Long-term sustainability of growth requires an environment that creates opportunities for all. Hungary scores well in some aspects of well-being, particularly in work-life balance, but trails most other countries in other aspects, particularly health status (Figure 2). Another strength is that the tax-and-benefit system lowers inequality, although there is a strong regional element in poverty distribution (Figure 3). Looking ahead, enhancing well-being requires measures that improve incomes and health for the population and particularly for retirees and disadvantaged population groups. Higher incomes should come from high-productivity jobs and good wages as well as liveable pensions for all – a particular concern in view of the acceleration in population ageing.
Table 1. Macroeconomic indicators and projections
Annual percentage change, volume (2005 prices).
|
2015 |
2016 |
2017 |
2018 |
2019 |
2020 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Current prices (HUF billion) |
||||||
Gross domestic product (GDP) |
32,592 |
2.2 |
4.4 |
4.6 |
3.9 |
3.3 |
Private consumption |
16,406 |
4.0 |
4.8 |
5.6 |
4.7 |
4.0 |
Government consumption |
6,505 |
0.7 |
1.3 |
1.1 |
1.1 |
0.8 |
Gross fixed capital formation |
7,223 |
-11.7 |
18.2 |
15.7 |
9.5 |
4.8 |
Housing |
631 |
9.7 |
16.0 |
10.3 |
9.1 |
3.9 |
Final domestic demand |
30,134 |
-0.6 |
7.0 |
7.0 |
5.2 |
3.6 |
Stockbuilding1 |
377 |
1.4 |
-0.2 |
-1.6 |
-0.3 |
0.0 |
Total domestic demand |
30,511 |
0.8 |
6.7 |
5.2 |
4.9 |
3.6 |
Exports of goods and services |
28,568 |
5.1 |
4.7 |
8.3 |
7.5 |
5.9 |
Imports of goods and services |
26,487 |
3.9 |
7.7 |
9.6 |
8.8 |
6.3 |
Net exports1 |
2,081 |
1.4 |
-1.9 |
-0.4 |
-0.6 |
-0.1 |
Other indicators (growth rates, unless specified) |
||||||
Potential GDP |
. . |
2.0 |
2.2 |
2.7 |
3.1 |
3.3 |
Output gap2 |
. . |
-1.9 |
0.3 |
2.2 |
2.9 |
3.0 |
Employment |
. . |
3.3 |
1.6 |
1.4 |
1.2 |
0.7 |
Unemployment rate |
. . |
5.1 |
4.2 |
3.6 |
3.2 |
3.1 |
GDP deflator |
. . |
1.0 |
3.6 |
4.5 |
4.9 |
4.3 |
Consumer price index |
. . |
0.4 |
2.3 |
2.9 |
4.0 |
4.0 |
Core consumer prices |
. . |
1.5 |
1.8 |
2.1 |
3.3 |
3.9 |
Household saving ratio, net3 |
. . |
8.1 |
7.3 |
10.8 |
10.6 |
10.8 |
Current account balance4 |
. . |
6.2 |
3.2 |
1.7 |
0.9 |
0.6 |
General government fiscal balance4 |
. . |
-1.6 |
-2.2 |
-2.4 |
-2.0 |
-2.0 |
Underlying general government fiscal balance2 |
. . |
-1.4 |
-2.3 |
-3.4 |
-3.4 |
-3.4 |
Underlying government primary fiscal balance2 |
. . |
1.7 |
0.4 |
-0.9 |
-0.9 |
-0.5 |
General government gross debt (Maastricht)4 |
. . |
75.9 |
73.3 |
70.6 |
67.7 |
65.7 |
General government net debt4 |
. . |
65.8 |
62.7 |
59.7 |
56.8 |
54.7 |
Three-month money market rate, average |
. . |
0.7 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
2.3 |
4.6 |
Ten-year government bond yield, average |
. . |
3.1 |
3.0 |
3.1 |
4.6 |
6.5 |
1. Contribution to changes in real GDP
2. As a percentage of potential GDP.
3. As a percentage of household disposable income.
4. As a percentage of GDP.
Source: OECD (2018), "OECD Economic Outlook No. 104, Volume 2018 Issue 2", OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections (database).
Inequality has remained low, even with the sharp rise in unemployment during the crisis. Poverty is relatively low, but has a strong regional dimension (Figure 4). Poverty rates are higher in the northern and eastern part of the country, reflecting local economies that used to be reliant on out-dated mining and heavy industries. As economic activity disappeared, these regions were left with high shares of public transfer recipients, such as enrolees in public work schemes, disadvantaged groups (e.g. Roma) and low-income pensioners. Inequality is highest in Budapest, reflecting the creation of many high-income jobs in the service sectors. Nonetheless, even low-income earners in Budapest fare better than elsewhere in the country.
Improving living conditions requires not only that production continues to move up the value chain, but also that local comparative advantages are better exploited and that left-behind regions have better linkages to the rest of the economy, which would add to productivity growth. In addition, improving the skills of the labour force is key to enable growth. Presently, there is a need to respond to emerging and widening labour shortages, which would benefit from higher female labour participation and better integration of job seekers. This is also important for preparing for the impact of an ageing population. The key messages of this Economic Survey are:
The economy is expanding rapidly, and macroeconomic policies need to be gradually tightened to prevent overheating and stem rising inflation.
Population ageing will eventually put pressure on public finances, particularly on pension and health spending. Policies should be devised and implemented early to head off these pressures.
Better mobilising labour and improving skills in poor regions, together with better links with regional and national supply chains, are the key to long-term sustainable growth in living standards.
Recent macroeconomic developments and short-term prospects
The economic recovery is maturing
Growth is increasingly being driven by private consumption, which is underpinned by expanding real incomes, reflecting strong real-wage and employment growth, high consumer confidence and supportive macroeconomic policy stances (Figure 5). In 2017, investment rebounded strongly, partly reflecting the start of a new funding cycle for EU structural funds. Higher housing investment reflects rising incomes, low interest rates and government subsidies, including for families with three or more children (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018a).
Business investment is supported by favourable monetary conditions and high profits, driven by the ongoing recovery in manufacturing production that requires capacity expansion as well as a higher reliance on capital in production in reaction to the tight labour market (Hungarian Central Bank, 2018) (Figure 5, Panel B and C). Most of the business investment is taking place in large and, increasingly, in foreign-owned export-oriented firms, particularly in the automotive sector (Endresz and Bauer, 2017, p. 14) (Palócz et al., 2016) (OECD, 2017). However, all of manufacturing has benefited from the investment upswing.
Hungarian-owned firms, which are mostly SMEs, seem to have increased their investment less, judging from the relatively slow expansion of bank credit to the corporate sector, though it picked up more recently (see below) (Palócz et al., 2016). The government has a number of investment support programmes in place for SMEs, including the Supplier Development Programme (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018a).
In 2017, exports accelerated as activity in Hungary’s trading partners picked up and as new production capacity in export-oriented firms, particularly in the car, and, to a lesser extent, chemical industry, came into operation (Figure 5, Panel F; Figure 6, Panels A and B). This development has further skewed exports towards transport equipment and machinery (56% of exports by value in 2017) and chemical products (12% of exports by value in 2017). Imports rose even faster in 2017, reflecting the high import-content in exports and strong growth in domestic consumption, narrowing the current account surplus.
Labour market shortages are emerging and widening
In 2017, total employment creation slowed, reflecting strong private sector employment creation and a decline in public employment Figure 5, Panel D). Moreover, the number of enrolees in public work schemes fell to just below 150 000, aided by increased search incentives for enrolees as the ratio of their (non-indexed) wages to the rising minimum wage was reduced from 77% to 59% between 2012 and 2018. The improved labour market situation has also benefited groups with weak attachments (including females, older and low-skilled workers and long-term job seekers) partly helped by the extensive use of public work schemes, vocational training subsidies and lower social security contributions (Figure 7) (OECD, 2016), (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018). Labour supply has increased as the positive effects of improved labour market prospects offset the ageing-related shrinking of the working-age population (Figure 8).
The labour market has been tightening significantly, as indicated by the historically low unemployment rate, the increasing number of firms having problems in hiring qualified workers and the more-than-doubling of the job vacancy rate since 2010 (PwC, 2018). Migration of skilled workers and increasing number of cross-border commuters are contributing to the labour market shortages. In addition, capacity utilisation has been rising since 2012 (Figure 9) (Eurostat, 2018a).
The tightening labour market has led to higher wage growth, which exceeded 10% in both 2017 and 2018 on the back of stronger underlying wage dynamics and higher minimum wages (Figure 10, panel B). A 2016 tripartite 6-year wage-agreement raised minimum wages by 15% and 25% in 2017 and by half as much in 2018. Further increases are planned for 2019-22 subject to annual reviews by the Permanent Consultation Forum of the government and social partners. These reviews should assess whether additional minimum wage increases will harm external competitiveness and employment. Employers were compensated by a cut of more than one-quarter (accumulated over 2016-2018) in their social security contribution rates to19.5% (Figure 11). Further reductions to 11.5% in 2022 are conditioned on continued wage increases, but the 2019 budget contains a 2 percentage points cut to be implemented in July (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018a).
Headline inflation has picked up and passed the central bank’s target of 3% (with a tolerance band of +/-1%) by mid-2018 and reached 3.8% in the autumn before coming down below 3% as one-off effects disappeared, reflecting that most of the increase had been driven by higher food and energy prices (Figure 10, panel A). Core inflation (excluding energy and food) has started increasing, before stabilising around 2 ½% in the autumn. Nonetheless, surveys from spring 2018 indicated low inflation expectations at that point in time (Central Bank of Hungary, 2018a). More recent EU surveys confirm this pattern into the summer, before household inflation expectations started to edge up.
Since 2015, labour productivity growth has been well below real wage growth, leading to higher unit labour costs. The associated increase in the wage share has been larger than in other CEEC countries (Figure 12). The share remains lower than in the 2010s. However, if wage growth continues to outpace productivity growth in the same manner, then the wage share will be higher than at the peak of the previous cycle, while contributing to higher unit labour costs. Wage competitiveness is not yet a risk factor, but continued rising wages could put pressure on external competitiveness in the near future. Such a development could discourage inwards FDI. On the other hand, rising wages are also an integral part of incomes catching up towards richer OECD countries. Moreover, higher wages could stem emigration of high-skilled workers and attract skilled labour. This would support a shift to higher productivity activities, increasing the attractiveness for foreign investors and furthering growth.
Bolstering productivity growth has to address the dichotomy between the mainly foreign-owned, export-oriented and innovative firms with strong growth and profits, and the domestic SME sector with low productivity growth, little technological spill-over and a low propensity to innovate (European Commission Staff Working Document, 2018). This requires more competition on domestic markets to foster competitive firms, pointing to a need for reduced regulatory barriers and improved regulatory policy formulation as discussed in the previous Survey (OECD, 2016a) (Bania et al., 2017). More competitive firms would also have stronger investment incentives, but human capital also needs to be enhanced, especially in skills upgrading and on-the-job training of workers (OECD, 2016a).
Prospects and risks
Economic activity remained strong in 2018 but will moderate in 2019 as capacity constraints tighten further. This means that demand will increasingly be met through imports and inflation will continue to rise. Private consumption will progressively drive growth, as real incomes continue to expand and household savings fall. Public investment is set to gradually slow as the EU funding cycle matures. Business investment will continue to respond to the need for expanding production capacity. Exports will be supported by external demand and new industrial capacity, but rising costs will slow gains in export market shares. The pace of import growth is driven by domestic demand and will continue to exceed that of exports, further reducing the current account surplus.
An escalation of international trade disputes could cut demand for Hungary’s exports, and undermine investor confidence. Faster-than-expected wage increases could spill over into prices and unhinge inflation expectations, requiring an abrupt change in policy stances, which would exaggerate the boom-bust business cycle pattern. If productivity growth fails to catch up to the increases in real wages, then external competitiveness would be eroded, reducing export growth and Hungary’s attractiveness to inward FDI. On the other hand, stronger-than-expected productivity gains would bolster the capability to absorb rapid wage gains and secure faster income convergence.
Besides these risks, the economy is exposed to some potential vulnerabilities, which have low probabilities but have large impacts on the economy. These include renewed turbulence in international financial market that would reduce banks' willingness to lend, hurting investments and other events (Table 2).
Table 2. Potential vulnerabilities of the Hungarian economy
Shock |
Possible impact |
---|---|
A sharp increase in geopolitical tensions, particularly in Europe. |
Such tensions would lead to investors seeking refuge in safe harbours, potentially precipitating currency outflows from Hungary owing to interest-rate differentials and recent currency fluctuations, with knock-on effects on inward private sector investment. |
Emerging market economies turbulence spreading to Hungary |
A sharp currency depreciation could force an abrupt and large increase in monetary policy rates, resulting in a confidence crisis that suppress growth |
A sharp reduction of EU funding of structural Programmes in the next funding period starting in 2021. |
A deterioration in funding would severely hamper implementation of the government’s development strategies. |
Monetary, financial and fiscal policies to promote stability and well-being
Monetary policy is supportive
Policy interest rates have been unchanged since September 2017 when the overnight central bank deposit rate was cut to -0.15% and the base rate was kept unchanged at 0.9% (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2017a). In addition, the central bank used unconventional measures to lower the yield curve, although with limited impact for longer maturities (Figure 13) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2017a) (Virág and Nagy, 2016).
In September 2018, the central bank announced that it is prepared for a gradual and cautious normalisation of monetary policy, while maintaining policy rates. As a first step, some of the unconventional monetary policy tools – including a three-month deposit facility, a mortgage-bond purchase programme and an interest rate swap facility – will be phased out by end-2018. During the phasing out period, a Funding for Growth Scheme Fix will be introduced to encourage commercial banks to provide fixed-term loans to SMEs following similar programmes in the past (Central Bank of Hungary, 2018b) (Central Bank of Hungary, 2018c) (Central Bank of Hungary, 2018d).
The currency has fluctuated. In 2017, the currency appreciated against the euro and the US dollar, despite a widening interest-rate differential. In 2018, increasing volatility in emerging markets led to a sharp depreciation and higher yields more than reversing the previous appreciation (Figure 14, Panel A and B). This development addresses some of the concern that the currency may be somewhat overvalued (IMF, 2018). The currency depreciation also mitigated some of the increases in unit labour costs brought about by strong real-wage growth (Figure 14, Panel C). However, other economies with floating exchange rates have been forced to hike policy rates in response to large depreciations to stem capital outflows, irrespective of the fundamental value of their currency (Figure 15). Moreover, as real interest rates remain negative, in a context of rising global interest rates Hungary may be vulnerable to currency outflows as investors seek better yields.
International reserves have declined by one-third between 2014 and 2017, mainly reflecting the conversion of households’ foreign currency mortgages to domestic denominations. This also reduced the import cover rate below three months (Figure 16) (IMF, 2018). At present, this in itself does not give rise to concern and the latest IMF Article IV consultation concluded that foreign reserves remain adequate.
The currency depreciation has contributed to higher inflation, though less than other factors such as higher commodity prices and excise duties. The fast wage increases combined with rising inflation are likely to have contributed to the increase in inflation expectations since mid-2018. This calls for a normalisation of monetary policy to ensure that inflation expectations remains well anchored, including a gradual increase in policy rates and the continued exiting from unconventional monetary policy measures. The authorities may need to resort to earlier and much more substantial tightening if the depreciation continues under the influence of international financial disturbances affecting emerging markets economies, or if there is a faster-than-expected normalisation of international monetary conditions.
Financial sector vulnerability could be further reduced
Since 2015, the stability of the financial sector has improved markedly (Figure 17). Banks’ capital adequacy ratio is around 20% which – while improved – implies lower capital buffers than Hungary’s regional peers (IMF, 2018). The banking liquidity coverage ratio is 189%, providing banks with adequate shock absorbing capacity in line with Basel and national regulatory requirements (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018a). Other indicators also point to good health. Return on assets (ROA) and equity (ROE) were around 1.5% and 14% respectively by mid-summer 2018, close to historical highs, reflecting solid profitability on the back of historically high profits; although much of the profitability is concentrated in the largest banking groups (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018a). In addition, banks have continued to reduce their share of non-performing loans (NPLs). However, the level remains relatively high (Figure 18). The main problem resides with the household sector, which accounts for almost three-quarters of NPLs (90 days delinquency), while the share of corporate NPLs is considered to be in line with normal risks for such loans (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018b).
Further reduction in NPLs is facilitated by the strong economy, but may be hampered by a lack of an official trading platform and a framework for selling impaired loans. After fewer than three years of operation, the central bank sold the Hungarian Restructuring and Debt Management Ltd. (MARK), created to absorb bad debts to a private investor in early 2017 (OECD, 2016a) (APS Investment, 2017). MARK had an initial positive effect. Nonetheless, the sale runs somewhat against current European Union reform efforts to develop, among others, a secondary market for NPLs and prevent future NPL build-ups (OECD, 2018a). The central bank has introduced macro-prudential tools (including a Systemic Risk Buffer) to discourage holding NPLs, which may support the secondary market for NPLs. The Systemic Risk Buffer accelerates portfolio cleaning as it levies capital surcharges on banks that keep their non-performing loans beyond a certain duration or threshold as recommended in the last Survey (Table 3) (OECD, 2016a).
Another part of the European Union’s reform efforts is the continued restructuring of the banking sector. A sign of insufficient restructuring is that although the profitability of the banking sector has continued to improve, this has mainly arisen from non-core activities, such as trading, dividend incomes etc. (Figure 19) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018b). Without profits from non-core activities, a number of credit institutions (with a combined market share of 20%) would be loss-makers. More generally, the sector has the highest operating and staffing costs in the CEEC region, reflecting a combination of high concentration and a low degree of competition (Figure 19, Panel B) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018a) (IMF, 2018) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2017c). The government could spur competition in the sector through privatisation of the remaining state-owned banks to help foster the financial sector’s ability to contribute to growth.
Despite the improved health of banks, they only started extending credit again in 2017, and the volume of total credit remains below pre-crises levels (Figure 20, Panel A). Demand for mortgage loans has been stimulated by government measures (the Family Housing Subsidy Programme) as well as central bank measures, including a consumer-friendly housing loan programme and the promotion of fixed interest loans. Nonetheless, the household credit-to-GDP level remains lower than in peer countries (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018a). Some of the unconventional monetary policy measures are aimed at supporting credit extension to the corporate sector and particularly SMEs (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018c) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2017d). In June 2018, the overall loan volume to the corporate sector was 12% higher y-o-y. Nonetheless, corporate loans as a share of GDP has remained basically unchanged (Figure 20, Panel C).
Arguably, the banking sector could extend credit further. Deposits have grown faster than credits and lending is lagging economic growth, suggesting a nearly neutral impact on growth (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018a) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018c). Moreover, the gap between the credit-to-GDP ratio and its long-run trend indicates room for stronger credit expansion Figure 20, Panel B). This suggests that the withdrawal of all unconventional monetary policy measures together with a more competitive and risk-bearing banking sector would allow the sector to resume its traditional credit role.
Table 3. Past recommendations on monetary policy and financial sector
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
---|---|
Reduce tax burdens of banks and improve tax design. |
In January 2017, the levy on larger banks has been reduced from 0.24% to 0.21% of assets, although the tax on small banks, of 0.15% of assets, remained unchanged. Since 2017, banks are eligible for transaction duty reduction if their number of clients from financial services increases. |
Consider moving towards to a more neutral policy stance. |
In September 2017, the central bank has lowered the overnight central bank deposit rate from -0.05 to -0.15% and kept the base rate unchanged at 0.9%. |
Expand capital surcharges on nonperforming loans detained by banks beyond a certain period. |
Since 2017, banks have to comply with enhanced capital requirements, if their stock of impaired project financing loans exceeds 30% of domestic Pillar 1 capital requirement. |
Implement a strategy for the asset management company to step-up offloading of non-performing assets. |
In early 2017 the Hungarian Restructuring and Debt Management Ltd. (MARK Zrt.) was sold to a private investor, removing an official trading platform for impaired loans. |
The ownership of the stock exchange should return to private ownership over the medium-term. |
No action taken. |
Fiscal policy should be more forward looking
Fiscal policy is being loosened. On the revenue side, employers' social security contribution rate was lowered in 2017 and again it 2018 to 19.5% (from 27%), as recommended in the previous Survey. The corporate income tax rate was also lowered to 9% in 2017. The total revenue reductions are 1.8% of GDP in 2017 and 0.7% of GDP in 2018, constituting a permanent reduction in the revenue-to-GDP share, (European Commission, 2018a) (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018). Additional minor revenue losses, amounting to 0.2% of GDP in 2017 and 0.1% in 2018, came from the lowering of the VAT rate on selected products (European Commission, 2018a). The government’s main objective for this lowering was to combat VAT fraud. By contrast, the previous Survey recommended increasing the reliance on consumption taxes (Table 6). Moreover, these changes have added to a complex and administratively costly VAT system. This contributes to a persistent, albeit narrowing, VAT gap (the difference between expected and collected VAT receipts) which stood at 13% in 2016, the most recent figure available (European Union, 2018). Other smaller tax measures had an estimated budgetary cost of 0.1% of GDP in both 2017 and 2018 (European Commission, 2018a). The 2019 budget contains additional tax reductions for families with at least two children; another 2 percentage point reduction in employers' social contribution rate, and tax relief for small businesses, subtracting another 0.4% of GDP from revenue.
Public spending has been expanding since 2017, reflecting renewed disbursements from EU structural funds and an increase in housing subsidies (with a budget cost of 0.1% of GDP) (European Commission, 2018a). Moreover, in 2018 public wages were increased by between 5% and 18% as part of the agreed 30% cumulated public wage increases for the years 2017 to 2019, adding 0.4% of GDP to the public wage bill (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018b) (European Commission, 2018a). On the other hand, the lower social security contributions reduced the wage bill by an estimated 0.2% of GDP. The 2019 budget contains higher spending on security, education, unemployment benefits, and on transport and telecommunications infrastructure and services. Nationally funded investment projects will add 0.7% of GDP to spending in 2019 (European Commission, 2018a).
Overall, the general government budget deficit will have widened to an estimated 2.4% of GDP in 2018 before slightly narrowing in 2019, reflecting the fact that the budgetary effect of a looser fiscal stance is broadly offset by strong economic growth, leaving the revenue and spending broadly stable as a share of GDP (Table 4). The implied deterioration in the structural deficit mainly reflects the tax reductions (Figure 21). These have mostly focused on reducing taxation on labour and corporate income with positive employment and growth effects in the medium term, while the short-term implication is a continuation of a pro-cyclical fiscal stance (OECD, 2011). Given the risks of an overheating economy, the government should tighten the fiscal stance for cyclical reasons to avoid overheating and thus prolong the economic upswing. Fiscal policy should avoid excessive pro-cyclicality in order to build up sufficient buffers to meet medium-term challenges.
Table 4. Fiscal indicators
As a percentage of GDP.
|
2016 |
2017 |
2018 |
2019 ¹ |
2020 ¹ |
Spending and revenue |
|||||
Total revenue |
45.1 |
44.7 |
44.3 |
44.3 |
44.2 |
Total expenditure |
46.8 |
46.9 |
46.6 |
46.5 |
46.3 |
Net interest payments |
3.1 |
2.7 |
2.4 |
2.5 |
2.8 |
Budget balance |
|||||
Fiscal balance |
-1.6 |
-2.2 |
-2.4 |
-2.2 |
-2.2 |
Cyclically adjusted fiscal balance² |
-0.7 |
-2.3 |
-3.4 |
-3.6 |
-3.5 |
Underlying fiscal balance² |
-1.4 |
-2.3 |
-3.4 |
-3.6 |
-3.5 |
Underlying primary fiscal balance² |
1.7 |
0.4 |
-0.9 |
-1.1 |
-0.6 |
Public debt |
|||||
Gross debt |
97.3 |
91.9 |
89.5 |
86.6 |
84.8 |
Gross debt (Maastricht definition) |
73.8 |
71.3 |
68.9 |
66.0 |
64.1 |
Net debt |
65.8 |
62.7 |
59.7 |
57.0 |
55.1 |
1. Contribution to changes in real GDP
2. As a percentage of potential GDP
Source: OECD (2018), OECD Economic Outlook: Statistics and Projections (database).
The public debt-to-GDP ratio has declined since its peak in 2014, bringing it just below the OECD average (OECD, 2016a) (Figure 22. General government contingent liabilities remain at nearly one-quarter of GDP. Almost 40% of these are related to government ownership in the financial sector. In addition, one-fifth arises from government controlled entities in non-financial sector, such as the potential cost of the state-owned energy company keeping energy prices at internationally low levels, as raised in the previous Survey (OECD, 2016a) (OECD, 2018b) (Eurostat, 2018b). In line with the constitutional obligation to reduce the public debt-to-GDP ratio to less than 50%, the incoming government has reiterated its commitment to continue a gradual debt reduction. However, the OECD's estimate is that with the current fiscal policy stance the debt-to-GDP ratio will start to increase again after 2019 (Figure 23, Table 5, baseline scenario). Debt would increase markedly faster if the projected increases in age-related spending are not offset by savings in other areas (Not offsetting increase in age-related costs scenario). Similar effects arise if long-term growth fails to materialise as expected, for example if structural reforms fails to raise productivity growth (Lower GDP growth scenario) (European Commission, 2018a). Only fiscal tightening in line with Hungary’s Convergence Programme would keep the public-debt-to-GDP ratio on a downwards trajectory (Consolidation effort scenario) (Ministry for the National Economy, 2018b) (European Commission, 2018a).
Improving the resilience of small open economies, such as the Hungarian one, depends on achieving low debt levels (Fall and Fournier, 2015). In this sense, the current debt level, of which one-fifth is held in foreign currencies, is a potential source of fiscal fragility for Hungary with its floating exchange rate, particularly in a context of increasing financial instability for emerging market economies. In addition, a continuous lowering of public debt could form part of a pre-financing strategy to deal with the fiscal consequences of population ageing as discussed below. The government has already taken some measures to reduce the debt burden since the last Survey. The main fiscal and structural recommendations in this survey can substantially support the realisation of the government’s debt objective (Table 6 and Table 7).
Table 5. Debt scenarios
Scenario |
Assumptions |
---|---|
Baseline. |
A continuation of the policy stance of 2019 with a primary deficit of 0.9% of GDP Main macroeconomic variables are inflation around 3%, and real GDP growth initially increases then averages 1.5% in line with assumed productivity growth, as projected under assumed convergence with the European Union (European Commission, 2018) |
Not offsetting increase in age-related costs. |
Increasing spending on health and pensions will add an additional 3.2% point of GDP to annual government spending by 2070, in line with European Commission (2018). |
Lower GDP growth. |
Real GDP growth is 1 percentage points lower than currently projected in the EU convergence scenario for the entire simulation period. |
Consolidation effort. |
In line with the government's medium-term fiscal objectives as stated in the Convergence Programme 2018-2022, budget consolidation of 1.6% of GDP until 2022 and thereafter a budget surplus of 0.7% of GDP. |
Source: European Commission (2018), "The 2018 Ageing Report - Economic and budgetary projections for the 28 EU Member States (2016-2070)" Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs.
Table 6. Past recommendations on fiscal policy
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
---|---|
Continue reducing public debt in accordance with the fiscal rule. |
Since 2016, total debt-to-GDP ratio has declined further to 73.3%. |
Reduce government expenditures to further lower the structural deficit. |
No action taken. |
Continue the fight against VAT fraud. |
Since 2017, the compulsory use of online cash registers has been expanded to particular service sectors and from 2018, the use of the online invoice system became obligatory. In 2018, the VAT rate has been reduced further on selected products. |
Rely more on non-distortive consumption taxes. |
In 2016-2019, the excise duty rate on tobacco products will have been increased gradually, and the excise duty rate on petrol, petroleum and diesel has been linked partially to the world price of Brent crude oil. |
Sell stakes in state-owned banks. |
In 2016 and 2017 public stakes in MKB and in Gránit Bank have been sold, leaving Budapest Bank (8th largest) fully state-owned, Erste bank (5th largest) with a 15% and FHB bank (11th largest) with a 7.3% share. |
Table 7. Potential fiscal consequences of key recommendations
Recommendations with potential fiscal impact |
Impacts on fiscal balance |
---|---|
Revenue raising measures: |
|
Make up for revenue shortfalls from recent lowering of social security contributions and simplify the VAT regime by introducing a single VAT rate. |
A uniform VAT rate of 22% would be revenue neutral. Raising the VAT rate by an additional 5 percentage points would cover the 2.6% of GDP revenue shortfall. |
Link the retirement age to life expectancy. |
Increasing the statutory retirement age to 70 years in steps from 2029 will fully cover the projected long-term pension spending increase to 2.7% of GDP. |
Combat old-age poverty by introducing a basic state pension at twice the current minimum pension. |
Less than +0.1% of GDP. Capping pensions at 150% of average wages would fully cover the fiscal cost. |
Spending increasing measures: |
|
Improving the efficiency of health care provision. |
Restructuring health care provision is revenue neutral if savings from closing hospitals are spent on outpatient care. Establishing country-wide group practices would cost +0.1% of GDP. Other costs are negligible. |
Enhance the capacities and efficiency of long-term care. |
Full coverage of cash benefits and vouchers costs +1.2% of GDP. |
Expand crèche coverage to 80%. |
+0.2% of GDP |
Double duration of unemployment benefit to six months. |
+0.3% of GDP. |
Towards a more growth-friendly and equitable tax system
As discussed below, ageing-related spending pressures are rising with population ageing. Reforms may contain some of these spending pressures, but not all. In the absence of offsetting savings elsewhere, such spending would have to be financed through increases in the already high tax-to-GDP ratio (Figure 24). As an illustration, OECD calculations suggest that an increase of 10 percentage points in the social security contribution rates is needed in the long run. However, such an outcome would hurt growth. Insofar as it is necessary to raise additional revenues, this should be done in the least growth distortionary manner possible.
Property taxation, the least distortive type of tax, plays a relative small role in Hungary (Johansson, 2016). Immovable property taxes are optional and levied by municipalities (OECD, 2012a) (OECD, 2010). Raising recurrent taxes on immovable property could involve giving municipalities incentives to have a minimum local property tax or introduce a national property tax. Such measures would make the tax system more neutral vis-a-vis other types of investment and thus improve resource allocation (OECD, 2010).
The VAT system is complicated with a range of reduced rates on selected items. However, reductions implemented in 2006-2009 have not really benefited low-income groups (Cseres-Gergely, 2017). Thus, moving towards a single VAT rate would be less distortive. A single VAT rate could be some 5 percentage points lower than the current standard rate without revenue losses. This could be combined with better targeted social transfers to help low-income households (OECD, 2014a) (Cseres-Gergely, 2017) (Arnold, 2011) (OECD, 2012a). Moreover, tax allowances for families or owner-occupied housing are costly in terms of foregone revenues without favouring equity, and should be replaced by better targeted means-tested transfers (Rawdanowicz, Wurzel and Christensen, 2013). Expenditure in connection with family support is estimated at 4.8% of GDP in 2018 (Ministry for National Economy, 2017).
Savings in non-ageing related spending could, at least partly, avoid the need for increases in taxation. Indeed, the ratio of public spending-to-GDP is relatively high, particularly compared with other countries with similar income levels (Figure 25, Panel A) (OECD, 2016a). Moreover, spending is tilted towards general public services and general economic affairs compared with countries with similar income levels or size of public spending (Figure 25, Panel B). This reflects high interest payments on public debt and the relatively high share of the labour force employed by the public sector (including public work schemes enrolees). The public wage bill could be reduced through faster adaptation of e‑government measures and public administration reform that focuses on securing a competitive public wages and improving the quality of public service provision (IMF, 2018).
Addressing longer-run challenges to well-being
Broadening growth
During the crisis, the income convergence process halted and only started again in 2013 (Figure 1). The large reliance of inwards FDI to support the convergence process by building up a modern capital stock and linking production to global value chains has also resulted in relatively large capital outflows, reflecting the remuneration of invested capital FDI (Figure 26) (Jirasavetakul and Rahman, 2018). This is also reflected in a relatively large wedge between GDP per capita and net national income per capita and in a relatively low wage share compared with more advanced economies. Thus, achieving faster income convergence does not only rely on achieving faster growth, but also on going beyond the reliance on inward FDI and developing domestic growth drivers.
In 2017, the government established a National Competitiveness Council to further productivity growth and income convergence. The Council consists of leaders from government, private and public sectors as well as representatives from academia, and relies on inputs from ministries and the Central Bank to identify relevant structural reform. The Central Bank has suggested 180 measures in areas covering labour market, health care, education, research and development, regulation, and SME support (Palotai and Virag, 2016) (Magyar Nemzeti Bank, 2018d). Many of these have been discussed in previous Surveys, and this Survey focusses on widening the growth process to include less developed regions, improved human capital formation and better utilisation of available labour resources, including measures to improve health and pension systems. Implementing the key structural reform recommendation in this survey would already have a large impact on incomes (Box 1.).
Box 1. Simulations of the potential impact of structural reforms
The impact of the key structural reform recommendations in this Survey is simulated by using historical relationships between reforms and growth in OECD countries. The presented estimates assume swift and full implementation of reforms of reduced the effective maternity leave to 1 year, gradually increase the legal retirement age by 5 years and improved health outcomes. The transmission mechanisms are mainly through the associated increase in the labour supply.
Table 8. Potential impact of structural reforms on GDP per capita after 10 years
Structural policy |
Policy change |
Total effect on GDP per capita |
|
---|---|---|---|
Before reform |
After reform |
||
Health policy |
|||
A. Improved health outcomes that reduces the disability rate from 7.7% to 6% of the labour force |
1.8% |
||
Labour market policies1 |
|||
B. Increase the legal retirement age by 5 years |
65 years |
70 years |
5.1% |
C. Reduce effective maternity leave to 1 year |
3 years |
1 year |
1.4% |
Total A+B+C: |
8.3% |
Source: OECD calculations based on Balázs and Gal (2016), "The quantification of structural reforms in OECD countries: A new framework", OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2016/1 and Balázs (2017), “The quantification of structural reforms: taking stock of the results for OECD and non-OECD countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, forthcoming.
The large inflows of FDI have, in many respects, contributed to the emergence of a dual economy. Inward FDI is driven by multinational companies moving their production destined for their international markets to Hungary. The recent reduction in the corporate tax rate would support business investment, including from abroad, which according to OECD estimates could bolster GDP growth by 0.2 percentage point after 10 years (Égert, 2018). However, the intermediate inputs into their production are imported or come from foreign-owned sub-contractors in Hungary. Indeed, available evidence indicates that Hungarian-owned firms, particularly SMEs, do not benefit from inward FDI in terms of higher sales, employment or productivity (Bisztray, 2016). As a result, the benefits to the domestic economy of the integration into global value chains in the form of domestic value added in final foreign demand has been low (Box 2). The other important growth area is the capital region that has benefitted from strong agglomeration effects and increasing demand for business services.
Fostering the development of local SMEs is a complex process, since the ability for local firms to exploit their comparative advantage depends on how well they are integrated into local and national networks. These include physical infrastructure (transport, communication, etc.), knowledge networks (local education and research centres) and links with other business and policy makers to identify local advantages and to provide framework conditions. However, the high degree of centralisation of government responsibilities is likely to hamper this process.
Box 2. Economic upgrading through integration in the Global Value Chains (GVCs)
Geographic proximity to Western European markets, significantly lower labour costs, well-developed transport infrastructures and increasing agglomeration economies have contributed to high integration in GVCs over the last two decades (Pavlínek, 2015). Nonetheless, domestic value added in exports is among the lowest in the OECD (Figure 27, Panel A). This reflects that although more than 40% of all jobs are generated through participation in GVCs and nearly 80% of manufacturing jobs. However, many of these jobs are in less knowledge intensive activities, such as assembly in the automotive industry (Figure 27, Panel B and C).
Raising the value added from GVC participation requires either traditional process and product upgrading or better integration through functional and chain upgrading, i.e. entering existing or new higher value added GVCs, respectively (Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002) (OECD, 2013]). In all cases, policy measures to pursue such upgrades need to focus on promoting human and physical capital formation as well as the exploitation of local comparative advantages.
Sources: Based on OECD (2017), Employment Outlook 2017; OECD (2017) Skills Outlook 2017: Skills and Global Value Chains.
Hungary has gone from being possibly the most decentralised to the most centrally organised country in the OECD (Hoffman, 2014). Development policies are determined and financed at the centre. This leads to a situation where local development hinges on national priorities and where local authorities focus on centrally-financed projects, including EU funds (Kovacs, 2015). At the same time, there are few attempts to identify local economic advantages and develop local networks to integrate into regional or national supply chains (Hajnal and Ugrosdy, 2015).
To better adapt policies to local conditions, local authorities should be given more responsibility for identifying and implementing relevant projects to develop their local economies. OECD work finds that in an increasingly interconnected world local governments are well placed to provide support for local firms, while central governments are best placed to address inequality issues (Broadway and Dougherty, 2018). Project selection could be improved through greater co-financing, which would give local authorities a direct economic stake in selecting the best projects. Not all local authorities have the capacity for identifying and selecting projects, as they are very small or very poor. In such cases, local authorities could enter horizontal cooperation to generate the sufficient administrative capacity. Alternatively, they could be provided with administrative and technical support from higher levels of government (Bartolini, Stossberg and Blöchliger, 2016). In addition, such devolution of power would have to be accompanied by greater revenue raising powers for local authorities. This would allow the central government to withdraw from detailed policy analysis and implementation to concentrate on more traditional supervision of local governments to secure that the devolution of powers lead to improved outcomes (Phillips, 2018) (OECD, 2017b).
Regional growth can emerge by promoting agglomeration effects between cities and with their surrounding area through better functioning housing and transport infrastructures to promote geographical mobility and allow better integration into local and national networks (see below) (Ahrend et al., 2017). In poor rural areas, employment can be fostered by developing tourism and agriculture. However, there are only few measures in place for either sector to integrate into other sectors or exploit networks to move up the value added chains This often requires measures at the local level and could include branding and the creation of high-value added tourism experiences, for example through culinary services based on local produce (OECD, 2014). Social media could be used to reach new visitors and promotion of new tourist services to supplement traditional heritage- and culture-based experiences. Such initiatives have to be complemented with the development of a modern international tourism promotion strategy.
Faster regional growth and convergence will lift the low level of aggregate labour productivity part of the way towards advanced economies (Figure 28). This can be supported at the local level by lifting up the skills of workers, which would enable local firms to benefit from knowledge diffusion and technological adaptation to move production from low-skilled activities to higher-skilled and higher-value activities (OECD, 2017c; Morrison, Pietrobelli and Rabellotti, 2008; OECD, 2015a). To better support local SMEs, vocational schools should have greater freedom to adjust courses and curriculums to reflect the needs of the local labour market. In addition, the schools should specialise more to exploit economies of scale and scope, for example to better invest in modern machinery and equipment. This needs to be combined with stronger mobility incentives, both for students to pursue their preferred courses and for graduates to relocate to areas with job opportunities that match their acquired skills. These efforts should be supported by measures to promote life-long learning, for example individual learning accounts as recommended in the last Survey (OECD, 2016a).
Addressing labour market challenges
The labour market is shifting towards higher-skilled employment (Figure 29). This reflects that over the past decades, the service sector has expanded and industry has moved from mining and heavy industries to higher value-added production that links into global value chains. This has led to an increase in medium and high technological intensive manufacturing, although manufacturing accounts for a smaller part of overall employment (OECD, 2016a). Moreover, agriculture is characterised by very small farms, indicating considerable scope for growth-enhancing restructuring that would further reduce employment in that sector. These changes are taking place as firms increasingly search for skilled workers. Thus, to sustain growth it is becoming increasingly important to adjust and enhance skills, improve allocation of labour and mobilise all underutilised labour resources.
One of the main active labour market policy instrument is public work schemes administered by the Ministry of the Interior and provided by municipalities. These are being scaled down at a moderate pace. The schemes pay wages that are above social transfer and have been successful anti-poverty measures, but less so as an active labour market measure (ALMP) as until recently only 10%-12% of enrolees have subsequently found employment in the primary labour market. Since early 2017, the share has increased to 19%, partly reflecting increased job opportunities. The government should use the favourable labour market situation to scale down faster the schemes and to concentrate their use in poor rural areas as a poverty reduction measure.
The schemes could become effective as an active labour market measure by moving the responsibility for the schemes to the ministry responsible for labour affairs to better link them to other ALMP schemes and labour market institutions. In addition, the provision could involve the private sector to strengthen activities that links better to the requirements in primary labour market. Also, the training content could be enhanced further and better linked to skill requirements in the primary labour market. Combining this with mobility measures would further improve transition into the primary labour market as many of the low-skilled enrolees live in rural areas with limited economic activity.
The increasing labour scarcity and the continued restructuring of the economy mean that improved labour resource allocation is becoming more important to sustain growth. The turnover on the labour market is relatively low despite flexible labour market institutions (Figure 30). On the other hand, the allocation process is hampered by a lack of geographical mobility. This is related to a rigid housing market (only 7% of households moved within a two-year period – less than a third of the rate in the Nordic countries) dominated by owner-occupation and poor quality secondary and tertiary road infrastructure that add to commuting costs (McGowan, 2015). The rental segment of the housing market is very small (and increasingly targeting higher income tenants) and the government should ensure that taxation of investments in private rental and owner-occupation is neutral.
The short 3-months duration of unemployment benefits bolster participation incentives. On the other hand, the short duration also reduces job search and matching incentives, contributing to labour market mismatches (Figure 31). Part of the mismatch problem is cyclical, reflecting that employers have increasing problems of finding qualified workers. On the other hand, the very short duration of unemployment benefits gives unemployed insufficient time to find employment that matches their skills. Extending duration, to for example 6 months, would address this issue. Furthermore, search incentives could be enhanced by reducing benefits over time while providing mobility support for interviews and first phase of employment.
The female labour market situation has improved significantly, in many ways restoring the pre-transition situation of high female labour force participation and gender equality in education (Avlijas, 2016) (United Nations Development Fund for Women, 2006) (Czibere, 2014). By 2016, the female employment rate had reached a new high of around 60%, which is similar to the EU average, but more than 10 percentage points below best performers. The exception, however, is mothers with young children (below 6), who have much lower employment rates (Figure 32) (OECD, 2018c). This reflects leave that can last up to three years (consisting of six months maternity leave, 18 months parental leave and an additional year on lower benefits). The crèche system is being expanded in line with recommendations in the previous Survey (Table 9). The current enrolment rate of 17.5% is higher than in Hungary’s regional peers, but is still less than half the OECD average, often leading mothers to take the full leave period (Gábos, 2017) (Századvég, 2016). In addition, kindergartens have become mandatory from the age of 3 (boosting enrolment to 95.7% and thus surpassing the EU benchmark of 95%), but often have rigid opening hours (legislative requirements are 8 hours and usually kindergartens close early) which complicate achieving good work-life balances (Hermann, Bobkov and Csoba, 2014).
The overall gender pay gap is 9% – 5 percentage points below the EU average. However, the combined long leave periods for maternity reasons reduce the incentive to hire young females and hurt their career prospects, which leads to a widening gender wage gap as education and skills requirements increase (Figure 33). The newly established Family and Career point programme supports returning mothers through training, coaching, and mentoring programmes. This is also reflected a relatively wide gap in the top income quintile with a 34% difference in pay between male and female managers – the largest in the EU (Sik, Csaba and Hann, 2013) (Szabó, 2017). Indeed, one-third of companies are headed by a female director, but rarely in highly paid executive jobs for large companies (Bisnote, 2017).
Table 9. Past recommendations on labour market
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
Further reduce tax wedge on low salaries and better target existing cuts in social security contributions. |
Tax wedge has been reduced by decreasing employers' social contributions by 7.5 percentage points. In 2018, the family tax base allowance for families with two children has been increased by 17%. |
Avoid increasing the minimum wage by more than warranted by inflation and productivity developments, and consider even freezing it for some time. |
The 2016 tripartite 6-year wage-agreement raised the minimum wage and the guaranteed wage minimum for skilled workers by 15% and 25% in 2017, respectively, and by 8% and 12% in 2018. In parallel, employers’ social security contributions were cut. |
Improve reintegration of public works participants. |
Since 2018, NGOs cooperating with PES provide: a) counselling and mentoring services; and b) financial benefits for disadvantaged jobseekers to foster their re-entry into the labour market. The 2017 “From the public work to the primary labour market" programme encourages public workers to find a job in the primary labour market by providing them benefits. |
Improve the evaluation of the efficiency of existing training programmes to better match different categories of participants to specific training programmes. |
Since 2016, PES has created individual action plans for all registered job seekers based on client profiling. |
Tighten the conditions for public work schemes by efficient implementation of a profiling system. |
In 2016, a new client profiling system was implemented to improve targeting of the public work schemes. |
Facilitate visa requirements to attract high-skilled immigrants in potential skill shortage domains. |
No action taken. |
Expand early childhood care. |
From January 2017, all local governments are required to organise crèche services where such services are demanded. |
Reduce the effective length of parental leave and provide incentives for paternity leave |
No action taken. |
Bolstering the employment rate of young women with children would support growth, preserve human capital, enhance available labour resources and expand female lifetime income, and particularly their pensions (OECD, 2012b) (Kinloch, 2015). The three-year leave period for maternity reasons is internationally long. For example, the Nordic countries have paid leave periods of one year or less, and they have some of the lowest gender gaps in the OECD. The government should enhance incentives for mothers to participate in the labour market. This should reduce the effective length of parental leave. This should be combined with greater possibilities for transforming part of it into paternity leave as recommended in the last Survey (OECD, 2016a). This would have to be accompanied by a large expansion of childcare facilities. The latter could be accelerated by incentivising the private sector through tax breaks to provide company based care, as in France. With a corporate tax rate of 9% the value of such breaks would be relatively low and may need to be complimented with more direct subsidies in addition to the financial support for workplace crèches (Brosses, 2012) (Varga, 2016) (OECD, 2016a) (European Commission Staff Working Document, 2018).
Working mothers also need more flexible working arrangements to secure an acceptable work-life balance. The government has already lowered social security contribution for employers hiring mothers with young children, allowed working mothers to receive maternity benefits after the child's first birthday and obliged employers to allow mothers to return on a part-time basis. The last, however, could potentially discourage firms from hiring young women, particularly in SMEs, or channel women into different and lower ("mommy track") career paths.
A better approach would be more flexible working arrangements with respect to daily working hours, teleworking, etc. that serve the needs of both employers and employees. The Labour Code allows for some flexible employment opportunities, such as the right for part-time employment for parents. Moreover, European Union co-financed programmes promote flexible employment in SMEs. Nonetheless, only a fraction of workers has such entitlements. In other countries (i.e. UK, Belgium, Germany) employees have the right to request flexible work schedule. The public sector could also lead by example by creating a flexible and inclusive working environment (OECD, 2016b).
Work-life balance could be improved further with more equal division of caring responsibilities, such as in Germany where the second parent's leave is added to overall leave period (Unterhofer and Wrohlich, 2017). The literature has pointed to other problems, such as a lack of role models (ILO, 2016) and gender stereotyping in the education system (United Nations, 2016). Career counselling or board representation rules could counter such problems (Wade et al., 2010) (Thomas, 2016). The complexities of achieving the proper work-life balance in the context of a dynamic Hungarian economic development point to a need for further research in this area.
The population is ageing
Population ageing will double the old-age dependency ratio over the next fifty years, reflecting an increasing number of longer-lived pensioners (life expectancy is projected to increase by 10 years). This development puts upwards pressure on public spending (Table 10) (European Commission, 2018b). In the medium-term, pension spending is actually projected to decline as a share of GDP, reflecting that price indexation leads to slower growth of pension expenditures than nominal GDP. OECD work, however, suggests that ageing-related cost increases may be even higher if additional cost pressures are included. These are related to a tendency for service sector wages to increase faster than productivity growth and the implementation of more costly technology, among others, in the health sector. This could lead to increases in ageing-related spending that is more than twice the EU projections and more than average increases in the OECD (Figure 34; Table 10) (Guillemette and Turner, 2018). Moreover, EU’s projections are dependent on assumed developments in key variables. For example, if the fertility rate fails to increase as assumed, expenditures could be 1.9% of GDP higher in 2070. Likewise, if life expectancy increases by two years more than assumed, then the increase in public expenditure could be 0.6% of GDP higher in 2070.
Table 10. Ageing-related expenditure are projected to increase
As a percentage of GDP
|
2020 |
2030 |
2040 |
2050 |
2060 |
2070 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total public pensions |
9.0 |
8.4 |
9.4 |
10.6 |
11.1 |
11.2 |
of which : |
||||||
Old-age and early pensions |
7.4 |
7.0 |
8.2 |
9.5 |
10.1 |
10.2 |
Disability pensions |
0.7 |
0.7 |
0.7 |
0.6 |
0.5 |
0.6 |
Survivors pensions |
0.8 |
0.6 |
0.5 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
0.4 |
Other |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
Projected spending on health care¹ |
5.1 |
5.4 |
5.6 |
5.8 |
5.8 |
5.7 |
Long-term care spending as % of GDP1 |
0.7 |
0.8 |
0.9 |
1.0 |
1.1 |
1.1 |
Total ageing related spending |
14.8 |
14.6 |
15.9 |
17.4 |
18.0 |
18.0 |
Old-age dependency ratio (15-64) |
31.3 |
35.2 |
41.8 |
49.1 |
53.2 |
52.0 |
1. AWG reference scenario
Source: European Commission (2018), "The 2018 Ageing Report - Economic & Budgetary Projections for the 28 EU Member States (2016-2070)", Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Institutional Paper 079, Luxembourg.
Ageing comes in two waves with the first large post-war generation currently entering retirement and another wave starting after 2030, accelerating the increase in the old-age dependency ratio with a peak of 53% in 2060 – two-thirds higher than today (Figure 35). The associated expected increase in ageing-related spending is comparable with the average in the European Union (AWG, 2018).
The pension system is centred on an earnings-related mandatory defined benefit pay-as-you-go public scheme. For workers with full careers, the system provides relatively good pension benefits with pre-tax replacement rates of nearly 60% for workers with average earnings (OECD, 2017d). For others, there is a risk of old-age poverty. Indeed, a worker paid the minimum wage will after 20 years only receive around EUR 150 per month, reflecting that the impact of career breaks on pension entitlements is larger than elsewhere in the OECD (OECD, 2017e). Moreover, pensions are indexed to consumer prices, which means that benefits will fall relative to wages over time, leading to a high risk of increasing income inequality between pensioners and wage earners. Already today about 20% of all pensioners receive pension benefits that are below the poverty line (defined as half the median income) and another 20% that have pension benefits that are less than 25% above the poverty line.
Addressing old-age poverty problems have to tackle initial low pensions and declining benefit ratios, as also raised in previous Surveys (Table 11). Currently, pensioners that have not accrued sufficient rights in the public PAYG system will receive social benefits that amount to around EUR 80 per month – one-quarter of the poverty line (OECD, 2017c). These pensioners qualify for monetary and in-kind benefits, although the combined value would tend to be less than one quarter of their benefit income. Furthermore, a number of pensioners (mostly with careers disrupted by the transition to the market economy) receive a minimum pension that is twice the social benefits, but this minimum pension will play no role in the future other than as a benchmark for regulating social benefits.
Table 11. Past recommendations on pension reform
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
---|---|
Take steps to secure an increasing effective retirement age. |
No action taken. |
Continue to ensure that the indexation of pensions does not lead to old-age poverty problems. |
Pension premiums were granted in 2017 and 2018. |
Consider options for diversifying income sources for pensioners. |
From 2019, working retirees and their employers became exempt from social security contributions. |
Bring forward the increases in the statutory retirement age. |
Retirement age increases have been capped at 65 years of age for both men and women. |
The initial low pensions could be addressed by introducing a basic state pension available to all irrespective of contributions. The budgetary costs of such a measure would be negligible if such a pension is set equal to the minimum pension (currently about EUR 90 per month). A state pension twice as high would costs less than 0.1% of GDP and could be fully financed within the pension system by introducing a pension ceiling equal to 150% of average wages. Setting the state pension at the poverty level, would cost less than 0.2% of GDP. However, in that case workers on the minimum wage would only have accrued such pensions after 42 years of contributions, eroding labour market participation incentives. The problem of relative old-age poverty associated with price indexation could be removed by changing to wage indexation. However, the associated cost would amount to 3% of GDP by 2070.
Looking ahead, the ageing related increase in pension spending can be addressed within the pension system by lowering pension benefits, increasing contributions or raising the statutory (and effective) retirement age. The average replacement rate for a full-career average earner is slightly above the OECD average, but would have to be lowered by 8 percentage points (through reduced accrual rights) to cover the financing gap between projected spending and contributions (Figure 36). This would increase the risk of old-age poverty rather than solve it. Increasing social security contribution rates by 9 percentage points (roughly equivalent to the recent reductions) would cover the projected increase in pension costs, but the increase in tax on labour would have a negative impact on growth. On the other hand, increasing the pension age in steps to 70 would keep pension expenditure constant at just below 10% of GDP until 2070 (European Commission, 2018b).
A recent pension reform is gradually increasing the statutory pension age to 65 years by 2022 and has abolished most early retirement schemes. Linking the statutory retirement age directly to gains in life expectancy after 2022 would stem the expenditure increase even if life expectancy increases more than projected. To achieve the full effect, the rule that public employees have to leave their service at the statutory retirement age should be abolished.
The only early retirement scheme left allows women to retire after 40 years of contributions (including periods of maternity leave) without deductions. So far, take-up has been up to 80% of those entitled every year. If this trend continues, contributions to the PAYG system would be lowered by nearly 1% of GDP by 2070. The scheme is not actuarially neutral as there is no pension deductions for retiring early to reflect the fewer years of paying contributions or the more years spent in retirement. This can be achieved by abolishing the special exemption for females and making the current system of encouraging continued work symmetric. This would imply complementing the pension increment (bonus) of 0.5% of the wage for each month worked after the statutory retirement age with a similar sized decrement (malus) for retiring early.
From 2019, working retirees and their employers are exempt from all social security contributions. Nonetheless, additional measures are needed to encourage continued work. For example, public sector employees should be allowed to benefit from the pension increment. Another problem is that it is nearly impossible for workers to calculate future pension benefits. The accrual of pension rights is not linear, with high accrual rates early and late in the working career and low in mid-career (Figure 37). A linear system of accrual right based on the current average rate would be a more transparent system and provide better labour participation incentives. An additional problem is that the valorisation of previous earnings is based on highly cyclical wage developments, which translates into a large variation in pension benefits for workers with similar contribution careers, but retiring at different points in time. Wage indexation of pensions would remove this issue. A partial and less costly solution would be to base valorisation on a moving average of recent years’ wage increases.
Outside the PAYG pension system, another financing option could be to introduce a mandatory (second-pillar type) funded pension scheme. However, a similar scheme was abolished in 2010 due to high operating costs among other factors. Furthermore, this option would require very high contribution rates. OECD calculations based on a set of conservative assumptions indicate that contribution rates in such a system would have to be as high as 9%-11% of wages to cover the pension funding gap in 2070, eroding wage-cost competitiveness. Moreover, from an intergenerational perspective, the introduction of a second pillar system would imply that the current generation of workers would have to finance the current generation of pensioners as well as (part of) their own pension. Alternatively, increased economic incentives, particularly for employers, in the third pillar of voluntary pension savings could encourage private pre-funding, supplementing public prefunding strategies. Such measures could for example include flat-rate subsidies and matching contributions (Italy, New Zealand, the United Kingdom and Turkey) (OECD, 2016c). Such measures often carry substantial fiscal costs, but the scale of the pension challenges is such that early policy action across many different policy measures is required.
Future ageing related spending pressure is likely to be higher in health and long-term care if the projected increase in life expectancy of 10 years, leading to EU convergence, is going to materialise. In other European countries, the gains in life expectancy are much smaller, but projected spending on average health care and long-term care is 3.6 percentage points higher than for Hungary.
The organisation of the health care system is highly centralised and reliant on planning with little reliance on price signals. The DRGs have not been regularly revised to reflect cost developments since their introduction in the mid-1990s, rendering them ineffective as a steering instrument. Instead, the Ministry of Human Capacities imposes global budget constraints, but as the ministry also routinely cover hospitals' debt, this has become a soft budget constraint. An additional problem in this respect is that hospital management is not rewarded for efficiency improvements, making them reluctant to impose strict cost control.
Only some hospitals have been converted into long-term care institutions, leaving Hungary's health care provision highly hospital centred. Moreover, average length of hospital stays has increased in contrast with developments in other countries and the rate of avoidable hospital admissions is one of the highest among OECD countries (Figure 38), pointing to a relatively inefficient hospital sector. Furthermore, emigration of health personnel has led to shortages, leading to uneven access, inducing the government to increase doctors' remuneration as recommended in earlier Surveys (Table 12). GPs are performing many tasks that in other countries are left to qualified nurses. The high work burden of GPs leads to a high number of referrals to specialists, but without a proper system of patient guidance, resulting in GPs having modest roles as gatekeepers and care coordinators, leading to inefficient use of specialists.
Table 12. Past recommendations on health care
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
---|---|
Increase wages of doctors and health care employees |
Since 2016, wages of employees in healthcare and the social field has been increased by more than 50%. |
Improve working conditions and replace outdated medical equipment by increasing health care investment spending. |
In 2018 a project funded by the EU (EUR 25 million) aims to improve the institutions’ medical equipment. |
Looking ahead, the health care system needs to become more efficient and better at adapting to change in the demand for health services, requiring fewer, but more specialised and better equipped hospitals. To achieve this, price signals must play a much more important role in the allocation of resources. DRGs create incentives for more efficient use of hospital resources (OECD, 2016f). However, DRGs need to be updated on a regular basis to reflect evolving cost of patient treatment. In parallel, the autonomy of hospitals, in terms of determining their supply and investment needs, also must be increased. At the same time, outpatient care, including day care, should be enhanced. In addition, GPs should have stronger incentives to function as gatekeepers by increasing the share of pay-for-performance financing (OECD/European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2017) (OECD, 2016f). The efficiency of primary care could also be improved by further promoting group practices for GPs (OECD/EU, 2016). These measures will enhance efficiency, but will not be sufficient to finance the increase in life expectancy. Access should be improved by updating and clearly defining a basic benefit health package that does not require informal out-of-pocket payments.
The organisation of long-term care for the elderly is fragmented between the health and social care systems with a strong division into providing either health care or assistance with daily activities with parallel financing and eligibility rules. Moreover, most institutional long-term care is provided by the central government and NGOs, while local governments provide the majority of home-based care. However, this organisation does not sufficiently take into account overlapping functions, leading to inefficiencies and reduced access, which should be resolved by creating an integrated long-term care system (Czibere and Gal, 2010). The government is introducing a new type of institution that provides more integrated care. Access to the, in many cases, more efficient home-based care is limited by labour shortages in home-based nursing care and by stricter eligibility criteria and reduced financing in home-based domestic care. As a result, provision is pushed towards informal care and more expensive long-term care institutions. The supply of long-term care options can be bolstered by introducing a (income-tested) cash benefit scheme and the supply of quality residential care homes by introducing a voucher system, allowing recipients to choose from competing institutions.
Greening growth requires mitigation of small particles emission
Over the past couple of decades, CO2 emissions have been reduced considerably, resulting in a relatively low CO2 intensity of production (Figure 39, Panel A). Most of the reduction comes from the restructuring of the economy, particularly the scaling down of heavy industries. Another factor is the expansion of renewable energy (mostly biomass), reaching 11% of primary energy supply in 2015 (Figure 39, Panel B). However, the potential for biomass use is reaching its limits, requiring a focus on other renewable sources such as solar, geothermal or wind technologies. In 2017, a new renewable energy support scheme (METÁR) replaced the previous feed-in tariff system with a combination of feed-in tariffs, feed-in premiums and competitive bidding depending on the capacity of the new plants, as recommended in the previous Survey (Table 13) (OECD, 2018d). Investments in renewable energy generation could be further stimulated by removing existing non-financial barriers, such as strict technical requirements or by better integrating renewable generation to the electricity network.
Table 13. Past recommendations on green growth
Recommendations in previous Surveys |
Action taken |
---|---|
Increase reliance on feed-in tariffs and use competitive auctions for renewable energy projects. |
The new renewable energy support scheme (METÁR) in 2017 has been introduced with a combination of feed-in tariffs, feed-in premiums and competitive bidding procedure. |
Increase energy use taxation, step up efforts at individual metering and consumption control and the provision of consumer information about the benefits of energy saving investments. |
Since 2017, energy suppliers are eligible for a tax allowance in case of an installation of electric recharging stations. |
A worrying development is high and increasing small particles emissions, resulting in adverse health impacts (Figure 39, Panel C). Indeed, Hungary’s mortality rate due to air pollution exposure is among the highest in the OECD with about 9000 estimated premature deaths per year owing to outdoor air pollution, raising health care spending (OECD, 2018) (OECD, 2014d). Other negative effects of outdoor air pollution include lower labour productivity and reduced yields in agriculture (OECD, 2016e).
The higher small particle emissions reflect an expanding fleet of old vehicles (the average vehicle age is almost 15 years) as most new purchases are imported used cars and increasing road freight transportation. The 2015 E-mobility Programme fosters the use of electric vehicles, but it mostly benefits relatively high-income households. To support the renewal of the fleet, the programme should be supplemented with road tolls and taxes that take vehicles’ environmental performance into account. Policies to reduce traffic congestion in urban centres, including congestion charges, as well as more steps to strengthen public transport and encourage soft transport modes, would reduce air pollution and boost productivity (OECD, 2015b).
Another risk factor in terms of particles emissions is obsolete heating systems in about 80% of the building stock (OECD, 2018d). Moreover, many – especially poor – households illegally use household waste for heating and cooking with an estimated one third of household waste used for such purposes (OECD, 2018d) (Ministry of Human Resources, 2017) (Mihalicz, 2016). The government should implement targeted measures to significantly reduce particulate emissions from residential heating. This could be achieved by accelerating and extending the replacement of inefficient and high-emission heating system of households with subsidies to poor households.
Bibliography
Ahrend, R. et al. (2017), What Makes Cities more Productive? Agglomeration economies and the role of urban governance: Evidence from 5 OECD Countries, OECD Publishing, Paris.
APS Investment (2017), Az APS felvásárolja a Mark Zrt-t a Magyar Nemzeti Banktól, http://global.aps-holding.com/hu/2017/04/10/aps-will-acquire-mark-zrt-central-bank-hungary-2/.
Avlijas, S. (2016), “Vicious and virtous cycles of female labour force participation in postüsocialist Eastern Europe”, LSE Europe in Question Discussion Paper Series, Vol. 119/2016, http://www.lse.ac.uk/europeanInstitute/LEQS%20Discussion%20Paper%20Series/LEQSPaper119.pdf.
AWG (2018), Ageing Report: Economic and budgetary projections for the 28 Member States (2016-2070).
Balázs, É. and P. Gal (2016), “The quantification of structural reforms in OECD countries: A new framework”, OECD Journal: Economic Studies, Vol. 2016/1.
Balázs, É. (2017), The quantification of structural reforms: taking stock of the results for OECD and non-OECD countries.
Bania, A. et al. (2017), “Impact evaluation of EU subsidies for economic development on the Hungarian SME sector”, MNB Working Papers 8.
Bartolini, D., S. Stossberg and H. Blöchliger (2016), “Fiscal Decentralisation and Regional Disparities”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1330, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jlpq7v3j237-en.
Bisnote (2017), Lassuló növeledés a női vezetők és tulajdonosok arányában 2017-ben, https://www.bisnode.hu/tudastar/gondolatok/lassulo-novekedes-a-noi-vezetok-es-tulajdonosok-aranyaban/.
Bisztray, M. (2016), “The effect of FDI on local suppliers: Evidence from Audi in Hungary”, Centre for Economic and Regional Studies - HUNGARIAN ACADEMY OF SCIENCES, Vol. MT-DP - 2016/22/Discussion Papers, http://www.econ.core.hu/file/download/mtdp/MTDP1622.pdf.
Broadway, R. and S. Dougherty (2018), Decentralisation in a Globalised World: Consequences and Opportunities, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/22265848.
Brosses, M. (2012), Work-Family Balance. Good practices from France, http://www.un.org/esa/socdev/family/docs/egm12/PAPER-DESBROSSES.pdf.
Central Bank of Hungary (2018a), Inflation Report June 2018.
Central Bank of Hungary (2018b), Press release on the Monetary Council meeting of 18 September 2018.
Central Bank of Hungary (2018c), Future Strategic Framework for the set of unconventioanl monetary policy instruments affecteding short-term yields.
Central Bank of Hungary (2018d), Considerations behind the launch of the Funding for Growth Scheme Fix (FGS Fix) an.
Cseres-Gergely, Z. (2017), “Expenditure responses, policy interventions and heteogeneous welfare effects in Hungary during the 2000s”, Institute of Economics, Centre for Economic and Regional Studies, Hungarian Academy of Sciences MT-DP-2017/4.
Czibere, I. (2014), “The Disadvantages of Women on the Labour Market in Hungary”, International Journal of Gender and Women's Studies, Vol. 2/3, pp. 37-47.
Czibere, K. and R. Gal (2010), “The long-term care system for the elderly in Hungary”, European Network of Economic Policy Research Institutes, Vol. ENEPRI Research Report No. 79, June, http://www.ancienlongtermcare.eu/sites/default/files/ENEPRI%20RR%20No%2079%20Hungary.pdf.
Égert, B. (2018), “The quantification of structural reforms”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1482, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/6d883be1-en.
Endresz, P. and P. Bauer (2017), “Corporate Investment in Hungary -- Stylised Facts on Micro Data”, MNB Occasional Papers 131.
European Commission (2018a), Assessment of the 2018 Convergence Programme for Hungary.
European Commission (2018b), The 2018 Ageing Report.
European Commission Staff Working Document (2018), Assessment of progress on structural reforms, prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances, and results in hte in-deth reviews under Regulation (EU) No1177/2011.
European Union, D. (2018), Study and Reports on the VAT gap in the EU-28 Member States: 2018 Final Report, https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/sites/taxation/files/2018_vat_gap_report_en.pdf.
Fall, F. and J. Fournier (2015), “Macroeconomic uncertainties, prudent debt targets and fiscal rules”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1230, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5jrxv0bf2vmx-en.
Gábos, A. (2017), Country Notes: Hungary, http://www.leavenetwork.org/fileadmin/Leavenetwork/Country_notes/2017/Hungary.FINAL.9_may2017.pdf.
Guillemette, Y. and D. Turner (2018), “The Long View: Scenarios for the World Economy to 2060”, Economic Policy Paper N° 22 (forthcoming), Authorised for publication by Alvaro Pereira, Acting Chief Economist.
Hajnal, G. and M. Ugrosdy (2015), “Use and Utilization of Performance Information in Hungary: Exemplary Cases from the Local-Government and the Higher-Education sectors”, NISPAceeJournal of Public Administration and Policy, Vol. 8/No. 2, pp. 23-48.
Hermann, P., V. Bobkov and J. Csoba (2014), Labour Market and Precarity of Employment: Theoretical Reflecions and Empirical Data from Hungary and Russia.
Hoffman, I. (2014), “The Changes of the Roles fo the Hungarian Counties: Towards a One and a Half-Tier System”, Lex Localis - Journal of Local Self-Government, Vol. 12/No. 3, pp. 393-415.
Humphrey, J. and H. Schmitz (2002), “How does insertion in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial clusters?”, Regional studies, Vol. 36/9, p. 1017−1027, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/0034340022000022198.
Hungarian Central Bank (2018), Inflation report June 2018, Magyar Nemzeti Bank.
ILO (2016), Women at Work. Trends 2016.
IMF (2018), Hungary - 2018 Article IV Consultation - press release and staff report, International Monetary Fund, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/CR/Issues/2018/08/03/Hungary-2018-Article-IV-Consultation-Press-Release-and-Staff-Report-46151.
Jirasavetakul, L. and J. Rahman (2018), “Foreign Direct Investment in New Member States of the EU and Western Balkans: Taking Stock and Assessing Prospects”, IMF Working Paper, Vol. WP/18/187.
Johansson, A. (2016), “Public Finance, Economic Growth and Inequality: A Survey of the Evidence”, OECD Economics Department Working Paper N° 1346.
Kinloch, E. (2015), The economic case for female labour market participation.
Kovacs, I. (2015), AER Study on the state of regionalism in Europe - Country report on Hungary, Institute for Regional Studies, Centre for Economic and Regional Studies, Department for Political and International Studies of the University of Pecs, Hungary.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2018a), Financial Stability Report (May 2018), http://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/stability-report-may-2018-eng.pdf.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2018b), Hitelintézetek összesen, http://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/hitelintezetek-osszesen.xls.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2018c), Trends in Lending, http://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/hitelezesi-folyamatok-2018-marcius-en.PDF.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2018d), 180 lépés a magyar gazdaság fenntartható felzárkózásáért, http://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/mnb-180-pontja.pdf.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2017a), “KAMATKONDÍCIÓK”, https://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/kv170919.pdf.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2017b), “75 milliárd forintra csökkent az MNB három hónapos betéti állománya”, https://www.mnb.hu/sajtoszoba/sajtokozlemenyek/2017-evi-sajtokozlemenyek/75-milliard-forintra-csokkent-az-mnb-harom-honapos-beteti-allomanya.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2017c), Aranykönyv, 2016, https://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/aranykonyv-2016.xls.
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (2017d), Túlteljesítették kkv-hitelezési vállalásaikat a Piaci Hitelprogramban résztvevő bankok, https://www.mnb.hu/sajtoszoba/sajtokozlemenyek/2017-evi-sajtokozlemenyek/tulteljesitettek-kkv-hitelezesi-vallalasaikat-a-piaci-hitelprogramban-resztvevo-bankok.
McGowan, M. (2015), Labour Market Mismatch and labour Productivity: Evidence from PIAAC data, OECD Publishing, https://www.oecd.org/eco/growth/Labour-Market-Mismatch-and-Labour-Productivity-Evidence-from-PIAAC-Data.pdf.
Mihalicz, C. (2016), Mérgező füstökben úszik a vidék, http://hvg.hu/gazdasag/20160312_fustkod_szmog_mergezo_hulladek_egetes.
Ministry for National Economy (2017), Macroeconomic and Budget Outlook 2017-2021, Ministry for National Economy.
Ministry for the National Economy (2018), Convergence Programme of Hungary 2018-2022, April 2018.
Ministry of Human Resources (2017), Az illegális hulladékégetés humán- és környezet-egészségügyi kockázatai, https://www.antsz.hu/data/cms83917/Tajekoztato_illegalis_hull_egetesrol_20171213.pdf.
Morrison, A., C. Pietrobelli and R. Rabellotti (2008), “Global Value Chains and Technological Capabilities: A Framework to Study Learning and Innovation in Developing Countries”, Oxford Development Studies, Vol. 36/1, pp. 39-58, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13600810701848144.
OECD (2018a), OECD Economic Surveys: Euro Area 2018, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-euz-2018-en.
OECD (2018b), OECD Energy Prices and Taxes, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2018c), OECD Employment Outlook 2018.
OECD (2018d), OECD Environmental Performance Reviews:Hungary 2018.
OECD (2017a), Hungary -- Trade and Investment Statistical Note, http://www.oecd.org/investment/trade-investment-gvc.htm (accessed on 5 July 2018).
OECD (2017b), OECD Employment Outlook 2017, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/empl_outlook-2017-en.
OECD (2017c), OECD Skills Outlook 2017: Skills and Global Value Chains, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264273351-en.
OECD (2017d), A Guide to Fiscal Decentralisation: Which Powers to Sub-National Government?, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2017e), “Country Profile Hungary ”, in Pensions at a Glance 2017, OECD Publishing, https://www.oecd.org/els/public-pensions/PAG2017-country-profile-Hungary.pdf.
OECD (2017f), Preventing Ageing Unequally, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264279087-en.
OECD (2016a), “Economic Survey Hungary 2016”, in OECD Economic Surveys: Hungary 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2016b), Be Flexible! Background brief on how workplace flexibility can help European employees to balance work and family.
OECD (2016c), OECD Pension Outlook 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2016d), Better Ways to Pay for Health Care, OECD Health Policy Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264258211-en.
OECD (2016e), The Economic Consequences of Outdoor Air Pollution, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264257474-en.
OECD (2015a), The Future of Productivity, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/ 9789264248533-en.
OECD (2015b), Governing the City, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264226500-en.
OECD (2014a), The distributional effects of consumption taxes, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2014b), Tourism and the Creative Economy, OECD Publishing, Paris.
OECD (2014c), The Cost of Air Pollution: Health Impacts of Road Transport., OECD Publishing.
OECD (2013), Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value Chains, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264189560-en.
OECD (2012a), Reducing income inequality while boosing economic growth: Can it be done?, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2012b), Closing the Gender Gap - Act Now.
OECD (2011), Taxation and Employment, OECD Tax Policy Studies, No. 21, OECD Publishing.
OECD (2010), Growth-oriented tax policy reform recommendations, OECD Publishing.
OECD/EU (2016), Health at a Glance: Europe 2016: State of Health in the EU Cycle, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264265592-en.
OECD/European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies (2017), Hungary: Country Health Profile 2017, State of Health in the EU, OECD Publishing, Paris/European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, Brussels, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264283411-en.
Palócz, É. et al. (2016), Survey and Study Paper on the Hungarian Investment Environment.
Palotai, D. and B. Virag (2016), Competitiveness and Growth - the Road to Sutaainable Economic Convergence, Magyar Nemzeti Bank.
Pavlínek, P. (2015), “Foreign direct investment and the development of the automotive industry in central and eastern Europe”, in Galgóczi, B., J. Drahokoupil and M. Bernaciak (eds.), Foreign investment in eastern and southern Europe after 2008: Still a lever of growth?, ETUI, Brussels.
Phillips, L. (2018), “Improving the Performance of Sub-national Governments through Benchmarking and Performance Reporting”, OECD Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, Vol. No. 22, https://doi.org/10.1787/22265848.
PwC (2018), Hungarian Automotive Supplier Survey 2018, http://www.pwc.com/hu/en.
Rawdanowicz, Ł., E. Wurzel and A. Christensen (2013), “The Equity Implications of Fiscal Consolidation”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1013, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k4dlvx2wjq0-en.
Society, R. (ed.) (2011), “Tax policy for economic recovery and growth”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 121, pp. F59-F80.
Sik, E., D. Csaba and A. Hann (2013), A férfiak és a nők közötti jövedelemegyenlőtlenség és nemi szegregáció a mai Magyarországon.
Szabó, Z. (2017), Szomorú statisztika: ennyire becsülik meg a női menedzserek munkáját, https://www.napi.hu/nemzetkozi_gazdasag/szomoru_statisztika_ennyire_becsulik_meg_a_noi_menedzserek_munkajat.631036.html.
Századvég (2016), Bölcsőde és óvódafejlesztések értékelése, https://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&ved=2ahUKEwiQsbPT4tXaAhUMDMAKHQEFAPEQFjAAegQIABAu&url=https%3A%2F%2Fwww.palyazat.gov.hu%2Fdownload.php%3FobjectId%3D71205&usg=AOvVaw0iWTsLWNzYLgNG6JHHL320.
Thomas, T. (2016), “Reconsidering Remedy of Gender Quotas”, Harvard Journal of Law and Gender, Vol. 11, http://harvardjlg.com/2016/11/reconsidering-the-remedy-of-gender-quotas/.
United Nations (2016), UN Working Group on the issue of discrimination against women in law and in practice finalized country mission to Hungary, http://www.ohchr.org/EN/NewsEvents/Pages/DisplayNews.aspx?NewsID=20027&LangID=E.
United Nations Development Fund for Women (2006), The Story Behind the Numbers: Women and employment in Central and Eastern Europe and the Western Commonwealth of Independent States.
Unterhofer, U. and K. Wrohlich (2017), “Fathers, Parental Leave and Gender Norms”, DIW Discussion Papers N.o. 1657, Berlin.
Varga, V. (2016), Nehezebb, mint bejuttatni a Yale-re - átalakul az óvodai és bölcsődei rendszer, http://nol.hu/belfold/gyerekes-dolgaink-1612561.
Virág, B. and M. Nagy (2016), The Bank’s unconventional easing is a success, https://www.mnb.hu/letoltes/marton-nagy-barnabas-virag-the-bank-s-unconventional-easing-is-a-success.pdf.
Wade, P. et al. (2010), Key Stage 2 career-related learning pathfinder evaluation, https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/182663/DFE-RR116.pdf.