This chapter seeks to identify and discuss “best practice” design principles for agri-environmental payment schemes. On the basis of a literature review, a Policy Spectrum Framework is developed to classify payment schemes based on key design features that are conducive to achieving cost-effective outcomes. Based on this Framework, an assessment of payment design options is developed based on their advantages and disadvantages.
Making Agri-Environmental Payments More Cost Effective
2. Literature review and policy spectrum framework
Abstract
2.1. Literature review
The literature review has been split into two parts.
General literature review to identify evidence on “best practice” design principles for agri-environmental payment mechanisms: this review is used to inform the Policy Spectrum Framework (Section 2.2). Three hundred and seventy relevant papers have been identified to date. Key papers (meta-analyses or literature syntheses, plus papers containing strong theoretical discussions about desirable properties of agri-environmental measure or discussing criteria for evaluating agri-environmental policies) were identified based on an abstract search and Secretariat expert knowledge.
Detailed literature review of choice experiment (CE) studies (“CE literature review”) examining farmer or landholder preferences for agri-environmental policy design elements: a detailed review of 55 choice experiment studies has been completed and is informing the design of the choice experiment component (a summary of key features of reviewed choice experiment studies is provided in Annex F).
2.2. Policy Spectrum Framework
Policy spectrum
Agri-environmental payment mechanism design is a broad field covering many different policy elements. A significant body of past OECD work (OECD, 2010[1]; OECD, 2010[2]; OECD, 2012[3]; Lankoski and Ollikainen, 2003[4]; Lankoski, 2016[5]; Hardelin and Lankoski, 2018[6]) has provided guidance on various elements of policy design. This work builds on these past efforts, and acknowledges that a key ‘frontier’ for agri-environmental policy design is the question of how and when policies should provide incentives for farmers based on:
The implementation of agri-environmental practices or actions: The basis for a payment is a defined farming practice or action including:
farm management actions (e.g. reduced fertiliser application, use of cover crops, conservation tillage, organic farming as per agreed requirements)
installation and maintenance of on-farm infrastructure for preventing and mitigating environmental damage or providing environmental goods (e.g. livestock fencing, buffer strips, constructed wetlands).
Achieving a specified level of on-farm environmental results or landscape-level aggregate environmental results: The basis for a payment is defined in terms of environmental results (whether measured or modelled) achieved by the payment beneficiary (whether an individual in case of on-farm results or group of landholders in case of landscape-level results). The payment can be based on achieving specific environmental result thresholds (either measured or modelled), for example, nitrogen runoff below 10 kg/ha or GHG emissions reduction by 20% relative to the baseline. Payment can also be based on abatement of GHG emissions or reduction of nitrogen runoff, for example, EUR 5/kg of nitrogen runoff reduction or EUR 30/tonne of CO2 equivalent emissions reduction.
Achieving a specified level of agri-environmental performance: Payment is defined in terms of achieving environmental performance measured by indicators or proxies for the potential environmental results, for example nutrient (N and P) balance kg/ha or environmental benefit index value. The payment can be based on achieving a certain performance threshold (e.g. N-balance below 50 kg/ha) or be based on continuous performance improvements (e.g. EUR/kg of reduced N‑balance). Hence, the main difference between the results-based payment and the performance-based payment is that the former is based on the specific environmental result measured directly (reduction of nitrogen runoff or GHG emissions) whereas the latter is based on proxies for the potential environmental results (for example, nitrogen surplus indicating potential nitrogen runoff or nitrous oxide emissions). Moreover, in many cases these performance indicators or proxies reflect several environmental effects (for example, high N-balance has implications to water quality, air quality and GHG emissions).
A combination of practices adoption and achieving a specified level of environmental performance or results (hybrid policy): Basis for a payment is defined based on a combination of practice adoption and performance or results achievement. For example, a mechanism which includes a ‘base payment’ based on practices and a ‘bonus payment’ based on results.
The question of whether, and how, policies should provide incentives for farms to adopt specific practices, or achieve a specified agri-environmental performance or result is important for at least two reasons. First, an increasingly large literature assessing the performance of existing agri-environmental payment mechanisms – the vast majority of which are practice-based – shows that there is significant ‘room for improvement’. Generally ex post evaluations have shown that such policies typically have limited environmental effectiveness and do not provide strong value-for-money (budgetary cost-effectiveness) (Batáry et al., 2015[7]; Coderoni and Esposti, 2018[8]; Dal Ferro et al., 2018[9]; Hardelin and Lankoski, 2018[6]; Lankoski, 2016[5]; Shortle et al., 2012[10]; Engel, 2016[11]). These evaluations often conclude that incentivising practice implementation, which may have tenuous connection with actual environmental performance or results, is an important reason for the limited environmental- and cost-effectiveness. In light of these findings, policy makers have in recent years become more receptive to considering alternatives to practice-based policies.
Second, advances in digital tools relevant for implementing alternatives (including targeted practice-based policies, as well as performance- and results-based policies) are reducing the costs and practical difficulties of implementing them (OECD, 2019[12]). Thus, policy options which even a few years ago may have been considered ‘infeasible’ due to high data needs or transaction costs may be more feasible now or in the future. Thus, policy makers have the opportunity to reconsider the feasible policy set. Table 2.1 sets out a spectrum describing the key options policy makers can choose from in this respect.
Table 2.1. Policy spectrum: From actions to outcomes
Uniform action or practice-based |
Targeted action- or practice-based |
Performance- based |
Field- or farm-level results-based |
Aggregate or landscape-level results-based |
---|---|---|---|---|
Hybrid policies incorporating practice-based elements with performance- or results-based elements |
||||
Payment is conditional on implementing specified practice(s) Payment is not differentiated across individuals, or spatially Payment generally made to an individual, but could use features such as agglomeration bonusesa or zonal-based eligibility rules to incentivise co-ordination |
Payment is conditional on implementing specified practice(s) Payment is differentiated (various options for differentiation based on different types of targetingb) Payment generally made to an individual, but could use features such as agglomeration bonuses or zonal-based eligibility rules to incentivise co-ordination |
Payment is conditional on estimated or measured improvements in farm-level environmental performance (may take into account a limited number of on-farm exogenous factors) Can be differentiated based on different levels of performance, or uniform payment conditional on achieving a specified performance threshold Payment generally made to an individual Could use features such as agglomeration bonusesa or zonal-based eligibility rules to incentivise co-ordination |
Payment is conditional on estimated or measured field- or farm-level environmental results (if estimated, taking into account both endogenous and exogenous factors) Can be differentiated based on different levels of results, or uniform payment conditional on achieving a specified results threshold Payment generally made to an individual Could use features such as agglomeration bonusesa or zonal-based eligibility rules to incentivise co-ordination (if not differentiating payment based on level of results) |
Payment is conditional on estimated or measured aggregate or landscape -level environmental results (if estimated, taking into account both endogenous and exogenous factors) Can be differentiated based on different levels of results, or could be uniform payment conditional on achieving a specified results threshold Payment could be made to a group or individual |
Notes:
a. An “agglomeration bonus” is an incentive paid if a desired spatial configuration of practice adoption in a given region is achieved (e.g. buffer strips adopted in all field parcels adjacent of given water course). Other types of spatial incentives are also possible: for example, an agglomeration malus instead rewards landscape diversity (i.e. penalises agri-environmental actions taken in adjacent units).
b The concept of “targeting” can be implemented via several different policy dimensions, e.g. one policy may target by restricting eligibility to producers in a certain area or who meet certain key criteria, but pay uniformly to all eligible participants; another may have open eligibility but may encourage targeting via self-selection by differentiating payments by paying more in areas where environmental benefits (or cost-benefit ratios) are higher
Framework for providing “best-practice guidance” on where to situate along the policy spectrum
The policy-spectrum shows that even within this particular ‘frontier’ of policy design, there are many different options available for policy makers. Therefore, the question naturally arises as to where policy makers should choose to situate along the spectrum, given their specific context. This section provides the first steps towards developing a framework for providing guidance on this question.
This report uses cost-effectiveness as the key criterion for providing guidance on ‘best practice’ agri-environmental payment mechanism design. Cost-effectiveness is a holistic concept that takes into account environmental effectiveness, different kinds of costs (e.g. compliance costs and policy-related transactions costs), and can incorporate dynamic considerations (e.g. policy impacts on innovation). OECD (2010, p. 17[1]) characterises cost-effectiveness of agri-environmental policies as follows: “minimising the costs, prior to remuneration for profit losses if any, of achieving the environmental goal…the cost-efficient policy instrument is the one that minimises compliance costs while achieving the environmental target.”
It is acknowledged that additional criteria beyond cost-effectiveness are also relevant for policy evaluation and guidance. For example, equity and distributional impacts may warrant attention in their own right, not least because the distributional consequences of a policy may affect its cost-effectiveness in the long term (Engel, 2016[11]). More broadly, behavioural and social impacts of alternative policy options may also be of interest, again because of their long-term impact on policy cost-effectiveness, or in their own right (Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]; OECD, 2012[14]; Engel, 2016[11]). Another potential consideration is ancillary benefits and costs, which are impacts caused by agri-environmental policy mechanisms, but which are not encompassed by the explicit policy objective (OECD, 2010[1]). Where relevant, this paper considers how different policy design options perform against such other criteria; it should however be noted that, compared to providing quantitative measures of cost-effectiveness, in general it is relatively difficult to quantify performance against these criteria or to provide qualitative assessments that are generalizable or comparable across contexts.
To date, seven key dimensions for assisting policy makers to decide on where to locate along the draft Policy Spectrum have been identified. Each dimension constitutes a desirable property of agri-environmental policies that is considered important for achieving cost-effectiveness, based on Secretariat expert judgement and the literature review, and also taking into account recently developed taxonomy to characterise agri-environmental schemes with special focus on those policy design features that are conducive to their cost-effectiveness (Guerrero, 2021[15]). An overview of the dimensions is provided in Table 2.2, and the seven dimensions are discussed below.
Table 2.2. Dimensions of cost-effective agri-environmental payment mechanisms
Policy feature |
Specification |
Key design options |
---|---|---|
Setting clear policy objectives |
How many objectives? |
Single objective Multiple objectives |
Can the objectives be quantified? |
Objectives are easy to monitor and quantify Objectives are difficult or costly to monitor and quantify |
|
Targeting |
Spatial targeting |
Zonal targeting based on environmental sensitivity (e.g. proximity to watersheds, areas with soil degradation) |
Cost-targeting |
Compliance cost thresholds in enrolment screens |
|
Benefit-cost targeting |
Environmental benefit based Environmental Benefit Indices (EBIs) Ratio of environmental benefits to compliance cost |
|
Eligibility |
Beneficiaries |
Individual Groups of individuals or collectives |
Farm type |
Intensive farming systems Extensive farming systems Farm size |
|
Other eligibility criteria |
Income Age |
|
Behavioural aspects |
Dispositional factors |
Resistance to change Flexibility Risk attitude Environmental concern |
Social factors |
Group behaviour, influence of neighbours |
|
Cognitive factors |
Perception of costs, benefits and risks |
|
Additionality |
Definition of baselines |
Historic baselines Current environmental performance as baseline Analytical baselines Dynamic baselines Baseline practice or performance requirements |
Tailoring |
Calculation of payment rate |
Based on compliance costs Based on value of environmental benefits Based on environmental performance or results Bid-based (conservation auctions) |
Uniform payments |
Based on estimated average compliance costs |
|
Differentiated payments |
Based on estimated differential compliance costs or environmental benefits Bid-based, auction mechanisms |
|
Advisory systems |
Training and education Communication platforms and information sharing Consulting |
|
Contract design |
Contract length Flexibility |
|
Hybrid schemes |
Mix of action and performance- or result-based payments Fixed payment elements Bonus payments |
|
Conditionality and Enforcement |
Monitoring |
In situ inspections Digital Technologies Self-monitoring Group monitoring |
Sanctions |
Expiration of future payments Reimbursement of past payments |
Notes: a. Note that design options may not be mutually exclusive: hybrid policies containing elements of more than one option are possible. b. Note that information-oriented policies (e.g. provision of extension and technical assistance, government-developed digital tools to assist farmers’ participation in policy mechanisms etc.) are considered as part of the overall policy mix, either as an intrinsic part of the agri-environmental payment mechanism or as a complementary policy.
Setting clear policy objectives
The exact policy objectives have an influence on where to situate the policy measure along the above spectrum, as the possibility of linking specific farm actions or practices to broader environmental policy objectives differs across objectives.
An important consideration is whether policies should focus on a single objective or on several. Noting that there are many linkages between on-farm management actions and various environmental outcomes, setting multiple objectives may allow a policy to take advantage of synergies between objectives (Engel, 2016[11]). However, given that actions to achieve each single objective are unlikely to be perfectly correlated, there may be both synergies and trade-offs to consider. Also, setting multiple objectives increases policy complexity and may result in increased implementation challenges and transaction costs, which may hamper cost-effectiveness. Studies in favour of either approach are identifiable in the literature: for example, Meyer et al. (2015[16]) recommend agri-environmental policies focus on a single environmental objective, whereas others recommend setting objectives which take advantage of synergies between related environmental outcomes.
Whether single or multiple, for any cost-effective policy it is important that objectives are clearly defined and measurable. Often this is not the case in practice (Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]). Objectives should be quantifiable to allow measuring whether policy goals have been achieved cost-effectively (Lankoski, 2016[5]). Biodiversity indicators or the definition of water quality levels could serve this purpose.
If suitable indicators can be identified, performance-based and result-based schemes tend to be advantageous and to deliver more cost-effective results (Börner et al., 2017[19]; Engel, 2016[11]; Allen et al., 2014[20]). Hitherto, result-based schemes have been used predominantly for biodiversity objectives and are claimed to be well suited, especially for the maintenance of existing environmental conditions (Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Allen et al., 2014[20]; Bertke, Klimek and Wittig, 2008[23]). When targeting specific species, results-based schemes can also be advantageous (Matzdorf, Kaiser and Rohner, 2008[24]); paying Dutch farmers by clutch of meadow birds, for instance, proved to be more cost-effective than remunerating them for specific mowing restrictions (Verhulst, Kleijn and Berendse, 2007[25]; Musters et al., 2001[26]). Practice-based payments often do not effectively protect biodiversity, since correlation between the prescribed practices and the desired outcome is not guaranteed (Kleijn et al., 2001[27]; Kleijn et al., 2004[28]; Zechmeister et al., 2003[29]).
Due to its complexity, however, biodiversity is difficult to measure. While some authors therefore express caveats for result-based schemes, others point out that suitable indicator approaches, especially for grassland, have already been successfully identified and implemented (Peerlings and Polman, 2009[30]; Wittig, Kemmermann and Zacharias, 2006[31]; Bertke, Klimek and Wittig, 2008[23]; White and Sadler, 2012[32]; Moxey and White, 2014[33]; Diekmann, 2003[34]). Further research and development of digital tools may facilitate quantification, which should render result-based schemes more cost-effective in the future. Yet, for objectives with outcomes impossible or too costly to monitor, or which largely depend on external factors such as weather conditions, practice-based approaches may remain the more appropriate option (Engel, 2016[11]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Hanley and White, 2013[35]).
O’Rourke (2020[36]) summarises some desirable characteristics of indicators for results-based policies:
They should represent the environmental issue that the scheme proposes to address and be directly linked to the environmental objective of the programme and the payment basis.
They should be mostly achieved by management practices and, to the extent possible, not be influenced by exogenous factors such as weather conditions.
They should be easy to measure, quantify, and observe by the farmer.
There needs to be a clear understanding on how farmers’ decisions affect the indicator.
Table 2.3 shows examples of indicators used in results-based schemes in OECD countries.
Table 2.3. Examples of indicators used in results-based agri-environmental schemes
Country |
Name of scheme |
Indicators |
Payment basis |
---|---|---|---|
Australia |
Box gum grassy woodland project (https://www.lls.nsw.gov.au/regions/south-east/grants-and-funding/thinking-inside-the-box-gum-grassy-woodland) |
Conservation value score of box gum grassy woodland |
Bid-based |
Australia |
Reef Trust Tender—Burdekin |
Reduction of nitrogen application (kg) |
Bid-based |
Austria |
Humus content in soil |
Ton of CO2 sequestered in humus |
|
Germany |
Harrier nest protection in arable fields (Weihenschutz) - Nordrhein-Westfalen |
Number of nests of certain bird species |
Forgone income from protecting nests/Per nest |
Germany |
Coordinated grassland bird protection (Gemeinschaftlicher Wiesenvogelschutz) - Schleswig-Holstein |
Presence of specific grassland-breeding birds species |
Per hectare in those areas where birds have bred. The payment rate increases with the number of nests |
Germany |
Species-rich grassland (Artenreiches Dauergrünland) - Baden-Württemberg |
Presence of minimum 4 or 6 flower species |
Per hectare in those areas where species are found. The payment rate increases with the number of species |
Germany |
Species-rich grassland (Artenreiches Grünland – Kennarten) - Rheinland-Pfalz |
Presence of minimum 4 or 8 grassland plant species |
Per hectare in those areas where species are found. The payment rate increases with the number of species |
Ireland |
Sustainable agricultural plan for the Macgillycuddy reeks |
Peatland scorecard |
Based on habitat management costs and the peatland score |
Ireland |
Managing the habitats of the Aran islands |
Habitat condition based on presence and abundance of specific species and management practices |
Based on management costs |
Ireland |
Protecting farmland pollinators |
Score obtained from the abundance and diversity of plants and pollinators, farm features and physical structures |
Based on the score and quality of habitat |
Ireland |
The Burren programme |
Score obtained from management practices and landscape characteristics |
Based on cost incurred and income forgone. The payment rate increases with the score |
Spain |
Biodiversity in grasslands and improved hedges |
Number of grassland species and hedges (characteristics and location) |
Based on willingness to accept methods for participating into the programme |
Source: Result based payments network (https://www.rbpnetwork.eu/).
Targeting
Heterogeneity is a natural feature of agriculture and environment linkages. There is a large spatial variation across landscapes with respect to productivity (and thus profitability of production) and environmental sensitivity. Numerous authors recommend a targeted policy design, which considers spatial variation of compliance costs and environmental benefits, to enhance environmental effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of policy (Espinosa-Goded, Barreiro-Hurlé and Ruto, 2010[37]; Broch et al., 2013[38]; Berry et al., 2005[39]; Matzdorf, Kaiser and Rohner, 2008[24]; Bartkowski et al., 2018[40]; Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]).
Effectively addressing spatial variation of costs and benefits in policy implementation requires good data on the farmers’ compliance costs and environmental sensitivity. In turn, this leads to greater administration efforts and increased implementation costs (policy-related transaction costs). (Balana, Vinten and Slee, 2011[42]; Engel, 2016[11]; Falconer, 2000[43]; Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]). However, some studies have shown that the efficiency gains from targeting can outweigh the implementation costs (Armsworth et al., 2012[44]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). For example, Lankoski (2016[5]) employs the ‘targeting gains ratio” to identify the budgetary cost-effectiveness gains from environmental targeting relative to the increase in transaction costs when more targeted payments are implemented. Targeting gains ratio varies across different payment designs, but is found to be as high as 28 in the best case, meaning that EUR 1 spent on public transaction costs for improved environmental targeting pays back EUR 28 through budgetary cost-effectiveness gains. Plausibly the gains from targeting are larger the greater the heterogeneity in costs and benefits (Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]; Armsworth et al., 2012[44]; Engel, 2016[11]).
A relatively inexpensive form of targeting is area-based targeting using geographical criteria, such as location near protected areas or proximity to watersheds, compared to data-intensive targeting at an individual farm-level (FAO, 2007[45]; Engel, 2016[11]). However, if environmental characteristics vary significantly within the area, site-specific environmental scores are a more suitable option. If farmers differ in their compliance costs, it may be useful to target low-costs sites and hence achieve a higher environmental performance with a given budget. Cost-targeting is often accompanied by payment differentiation (e.g. using discriminatory price auctions), remunerating the farmers by their compliance costs (Engel, 2016[11]). Wünscher et al. (2008[41]) propose that cost-targeting with payment differentiation may contribute the largest part of the increase in cost-effectiveness from improved targeting.
Cost-targeting is beneficial only when environmental benefits within region or across farms and field parcels are relatively homogeneous (Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]). With heterogeneity in both environmental benefits and compliance costs between farms, the two approaches should be combined to benefit-cost targeting. Specific performance scoring systems, such as the environmental benefit indices, allows policy makers to target the farms that achieve the highest environmental gains relative to costs (i.e. the agri-environmental payment) and thus improves budgetary cost-effectiveness. Numerous studies have identified efficiency gains from benefit-cost targeting (Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]; Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]; Arbuckle, 2013[47]; Barton et al., 2003[48]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]; Lankoski, 2016[5]; Hardelin and Lankoski, 2018[6]).
Eligibility
Agricultural and agri-environmental policies mostly target farmers or landholders. They can address either individual farmers or groups of farmers or collectives. Furthermore, they can be restricted to certain characteristics, such as farm type or size, farmers’ income, education level or age (OECD, 2007[49]).
Agri-environmental payments are most often directed to individual farmers for their conservation efforts, but could alternatively be allocated to groups of farmers to receive remuneration for collective actions or environmental results at the landscape level. The preferred approach depends, for example, on the environmental issue in question. When a specific spatial pattern of measures is needed to achieve an environmental objective, such as broader biodiversity conservation, or protection of species with large habitats, cooperation between land-managers can be beneficial (Franks, 2011[50]; Engel, 2016[11]; Mills et al., 2012[51]). Several authors claim that coordinated action or community commitment improves environmental performance or efficiency of a scheme (Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]; Le Coent and Thoyer, 2014[53]; Prager, Reed and Scott, 2012[54]; Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; Franks, 2011[50]). It can also reduce the risk of leakage by preventing relocation of harmful activities to adjacent sites (Engel, 2016[11]).
Another benefit of co-ordinated action is the possibility of mutual learning and the creation of social capital (Lastra-Bravo et al., 2015[56]; Mettepenningen et al., 2013[57]). By exchanging knowledge, farmers can not only share best practices and foster innovation, but can also decrease compliance costs, for instance by sharing machinery costs (Polman, 2002[58]; Franks, 2011[50]; Mettepenningen et al., 2013[57]). On the other hand, the requirement of large capital expenditures, conflicts related to timing of machinery usage, monitoring of depreciation and variable costs might make potential payment recipients reluctant to be involved in a group scheme. Effects of group payments on transaction costs are ambiguous. Farmers within a target area may differ in risk preferences, environmental attitudes, cost of capital, and discount rates in a way that may increase the transaction costs of group action. Some authors have stated that by grouping beneficiaries, transaction costs are relatively lower (Goldman, Thompson and Daily, 2007[59]; Jones et al., 2009[60]), while others predict an increase of transaction costs owing to higher coordination efforts (Franks, 2011[50]; Mills et al., 2012[51]).
Collective contracts can have positive impacts on compliance and enforcement, since it can activate normative behaviour and peer monitoring (Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]; Mills et al., 2008[61]; Cranford, 2014[62]; Hanley and White, 2013[35]; Sommerville, Jones and Milner-Gulland, 2009[63]), which might lower administrative costs (Dietz, Ostrom and Stern, 2003[64]; Dobbs and Pretty, 2008[65]; Mills et al., 2012[51]). On the other hand, many authors stress the importance of advisory systems or intermediary agencies to assist coordinated action, raising transaction costs for the implementing agency (Burton and Paragahawewa, 2011[66]; Moxey and White, 2014[33]; Riley et al., 2018[67]; Mills et al., 2012[51]; Franks, 2011[50]).
Another eligibility criterion can be the farm type, which has ramifications for participation rates and efficient attainment of environmental outcomes. Because of higher conservation benefits, several authors advocate for explicitly targeting extensive agricultural landscapes (Dahms et al., 2010[68]; Aviron et al., 2005[69]). Additionally, intensive farms request higher compensation payments than less intensive ones, increasing the cost of the policy (Breustedt, Schulz and Latacz-Lohmann, 2013[70]; Danne and Musshoff, 2017[71]). However, engaging with larger farms would allow benefiting from economies of scale, which contributes positively to the cost-effectiveness of the policy (Adams, Pressey and Stoeckl, 2014[72]; Espinosa-Goded, Barreiro-Hurlé and Dupraz, 2013[73]).
Behavioural aspects
The voluntary character of agri-environmental payments necessitates that policy design and implementation are attractive for farmers to ensure their participation. However, it is insufficient if payments are solely economically beneficial for farmers and neglect the fact that other factors might influence farmers’ decision-making. Thus, insights from behavioural economics can improve agri-environmental policy design in this respect. Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel (2019[13]) identify three different types of factors, which play into farmers’ considerations, additional to purely economic reasoning:
Dispositional factors which encompass the farmers’ personality, their risk attitudes and environmental concerns;
Social factors such as preferences for interactions with other individuals, social norms and expectations;
Cognitive factors which describe the ability of farmers to understand the benefits and costs that they are facing, their belief on outcomes and their own abilities to reach certain goals.
Acknowledging behavioural factors and addressing them through adequate policy design can increase participation and render agri-environmental programmes more effective (OECD, 2012[14]; Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]).
The most important dispositional factors are personal preferences on flexibility and inherent resistance to change, risk preferences and environmental concerns. Several studies have shown that farmers are resistant to change (Burton, Kuczera and Schwarz, 2008[74]; Sheeder and Lynne, 2011[75]). In Hermann, Mußhoff and Agethen’s study (2016[76]), for example, resistance to change was the reason for deterring conventional hog farmers from converting to organic practices. Relatively easy entry conditions with incremental increases towards more sustainable practices could be an effective solution (Öhlmér, Olson and Brehmer, 1998[77]; Schroeder et al., 2013[78]). Furthermore, specifically targeting farmers with positive or less reluctant attitudes towards change and sustainable land management can be beneficial. Both Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel (2019[13]) and Falconer (2000[43]) recommend to segment sub-populations of farmers with similar attitudes, which is especially relevant for group payments.
Besides change, rigid management prescriptions may discourage farmers from enrolling in agri-environmental schemes. More flexibility and less stringent restrictions are preferred by farmers and can increase participation (Engel, 2016[11]; Darnhofer et al., 2017[79]; Wittig, Kemmermann and Zacharias, 2006[31]; Klimek et al., 2008[80]; Ruto and Garrod, 2009[81]; Wilson and Hart, 2001[82]; Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]).
Result-based payments are an effective way to provide flexibility for selection of environmental practices (Matzdorf, 2004[83]; Bräuer, Müssner and Marsden, 2006[84]; Musters et al., 2001[26]; Gorddard, Whitten and Reeson, 2008[85]; Andeltová, 2018[86]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]), since farmers are free to achieve environmental results with the measures they consider the most appropriate. This allows greater cost-effectiveness (Casey and Boody, 2007[87]; Ferraro and Simpson, 2002[88]; Wunder, 2005[89]; Wätzold and Drechsler, 2005[90]; Casey and Boody, 2007[87]) because farmers may have better knowledge on local conditions and environmental interrelations (Andeltová, 2018[86]; Zabel and Roe, 2009[91]).
Farmers’ attitude towards risk is another relevant dispositional factor. Many authors state that risk preferences play a role in adoption of conservation contracts (Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]; Chèze, David and Martinet, 2017[92]; Kuminoff and Wossink, 2010[93]) and higher risks could possibly decrease scheme uptake (Loisel and Elyakime, 2006[94]). Others have claimed that “risk does not have a clear negative impact on the willingness to participate” (Matzdorf and Lorenz, 2010, p. 542[95]), also in (Trujillo-Barrera, Pennings and Hofenk, 2016[96]; Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]).
Results-based schemes expose farmers to a higher uncertainty of the amount of payment and therefore necessitate a risk premium (Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Andeltová, 2018[86]; Zabel and Roe, 2009[91]). The required premium is higher in cases where environmental outcomes are strongly influenced by external factors such as weather events or pests and hence beyond the farmer’s control (Schwarz et al., 2008[22]). In some cases these risks may decline over time when farmers gather experience and knowledge on effective management practices (Baumgärtner and Hartmann, 2001[97]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]). This makes easy entry conditions and higher risk premiums possible policy solutions which are particularly relevant at initial stages of the scheme (Schroeder et al., 2013[78]).
Environmental concern is often mentioned to positively affect enrolment in agri-environmental schemes (Toma and Mathijs, 2007[98]; Best, 2010[99]; Läpple and Van Rensburg, 2011[100]). This calls for social marketing programs, such as media campaigns or agricultural education services aiming at raising environmental awareness (Cullen et al., 2018[101]; Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]). Relative to practice-based payments, result-based payments tend to increase social networking, knowledge sharing and intrinsic motivation for environmental conservation (Matzdorf, 2004[83]; Matzdorf, Kaiser and Rohner, 2008[24]; Andeltová, 2018[86]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]).
Besides dispositional factors, social considerations are a crucial element in farmers’ decision making. It has been shown that behaviour of neighbouring farmers influences participation decisions (Damianos and Giannakopoulos, 2002[102]; Defrancesco et al., 2008[103]). Scheme adoption of neighbouring farmers positively affects contract uptake (D’Emden, Llewellyn and Burton, 2008[104]; Gillich et al., 2019[105]). Furthermore, there is evidence that peer pressure and social norms have ramifications on farmers’ decision to participate (Burton and Paragahawewa, 2011[66]; Emery and Franks, 2012[106]; Chen et al., 2009[107]) and fear of judgment by peers may increase the probability of scheme uptake (Emery and Franks, 2012[106]). Although Sattler and Nagel (2010[108]) downplay the relevance of judgment of others in adoption decisions, numerous authors stress that social networks can catalyse farmers’ behaviour (Polman and Slangen, 2008[109]; Mathijs, 2003[110]; Capitanio, Adinolfi and Malorgio, 2011[111]; Beckmann, Eggers and Mettepenningen, 2009[112]; Peerlings and Polman, 2009[30]). Peer effects can also help proliferate new practices. If learning is a primary barrier to the adoption of a practice or set of practices that achieve the desired performance or results, non-program participants may learn or be encouraged by their participating neighbors, and in turn later adopt practices, even without payment. If spillovers do occur, this increases the benefit-cost ratio of individual payment schemes as opposed to group payment schemes.
Cognitive factors play an important role in farmers’ decision-making. Here, it is important that the farmer fully understands the costs, benefits and risks and perceives them realistically. It has been shown that farmers’ perception of costs, benefits and risks may be distorted and does not always reflect the real measures (Michel-Guillou and Moser, 2006[113]; Doyle, 2012[114]; Bocquého, Jacquet and Reynaud, 2014[115]; Hardaker and Lien, 2010[116]; Kahneman and Tversky, 1979[117]). Immediate benefits weigh disproportionally more in farmers’ calculations than those in the future, and risks of high impact and low-probability extreme events, such as hail, tend to be overestimated (Doyle, 2012[114]; Bocquého, Jacquet and Reynaud, 2014[115]).
These knowledge issues can be tackled through adequate policy design by raising farmers’ awareness, education and training (Trujillo-Barrera, Pennings and Hofenk, 2016[96]). Access to relevant and reliable information is crucial for a farmer’s decision to participate in a scheme (Llewellyn, 2007[118]; Kallas, Serra and Gil, 2010[119]; Balderas Torres et al., 2013[120]). Precise information channelling and the provision of advisory systems are valuable policy elements (D’Emden, Llewellyn and Burton, 2008[104]; Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]), and can contribute to a reduction of communication costs and hence improve the efficiency of the policy (Defrancesco et al., 2008[103]).1 In order to tackle farmers’ tendency to value immediate costs more than long-term benefits, higher payments should be made at initial stages of the contract when farmers face high fixed costs (Duquette, Higgins and Horowitz, 2012[121]; Grolleau, Mzoughi and Thoyer, 2015[122]; Colen et al., 2016[123]; Dessart, Barreiro-Hurlé and van Bavel, 2019[13]).
Additionality
OECD (2012, p. 11[3]) defines additionality as “the extent to which the policy was a necessary condition for obtaining the targeted result”. Chabé-Ferret and Subervie (2013[124]) then define “windfall effects” as payments (or “windfall” gains) made in respect of actions which are not additional. For example, (Claassen, Duquette and Smith, 2018[125])show that additionality vary across practices for practice-based schemes in US agricultural conservation programs. Weak additionality means that a significant portion of payments are received by participants for implementing practices or management actions that would have taken place even in the absence of the payment. Achieving strong additionality contributes towards cost-effectiveness in that it limits budgetary outlays that do not directly deliver environmental benefits.
Assuring additionality necessitates clearly defined baselines and reference levels, which in practice are often lacking (Engel, 2016[11]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Ferraro and Pattanayak, 2006[126]; Casey and Boody, 2007[87]; Porras et al., 2011[127]). A baseline should consider the environmental condition at the beginning of the contract and incorporate the expected changes in external factors and land use that would have taken place in absence of the program (Naeem et al., 2015[128]; Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]).
However, a common practice is to use historic baselines (Angelsen and Wertz-Kanounnikoff, 2008[129]), which do not reflect likely future changes. While historic baselines can be computed relatively easily, they might punish farmers who have taken pro-environmental actions before the programme (Alpizar et al., 2013[130]).
Reference levels based on current environmental performance can mitigate aforementioned problem with historic baselines. By computing a farm-specific baseline, such as an environmental benefit index,2 the actual improvement can be measured and remunerated. Weinberg and Claassen (2006[131]) show an increase of environmental effectiveness by a factor of five when shifting from payments for “good performance” to payments for “improved performance”. Similar results have been found by Casasola et al. (2009[132]).
Result-based schemes directly link payments to environmental results (Matzdorf and Lorenz, 2010[95]) and hence have the potential to achieve high additionality (Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]). Furthermore, result-based schemes provide incentives to enroll the best-suited land for provision of environmental results and thus enhance environmental effectiveness and prevent adverse selection (Matzdorf, Kaiser and Rohner, 2008[24]; Quillérou and Fraser, 2010[133]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; Engel, 2016[11]). On the other hand, they also attract farms where the required results are already achieved or close to achievement (Uthes and Matzdorf, 2013[17]), which impedes additionality.
An effective definition of baselines is critical for additionality and cost-effectiveness (Bosch et al., 2013[134]; Porras et al., 2011[127]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]), and particularly important for result-based schemes (Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]). Setting the baselines right is a difficult exercise, requiring the availability of data and models on the landscape or even farm level (Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]). This is time-consuming and entails high transaction costs (Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Naeem et al., 2015[128]; Bosch et al., 2013[134]). The feasibility of baseline-setting affects whether practice-based or result-based payments are more suited (Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]). If administrative capacities are high and data is available at reasonable cost, allowing for the definition of effective baselines, result-based payments can lead to more effective environmental protection (Bosch et al., 2013[134]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]). If this not the case, practice-based payments are a better alternative, since they do not require reliable monitoring of environmental improvements (Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Colombo and Rocamora-Montiel, 2018[136]). Moreover, for practice-based payments, additionality can sometimes be roughly inferred by whether the participant had undertaken practice in the past.
Tailoring
The payment rate has important implications for budgetary cost-effectiveness of the scheme. Any rate above the minimum payment necessary to guarantee participation will overcompensate farmers for income forgone and extra costs incurred, thus reducing the number of participants possible under a fixed budget, and hence reducing both environmental effectiveness and budgetary cost-effectiveness (Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Ferraro, 2008[137]; Lankoski, 2016[5]) (Balderas Torres et al., 2013[120]; Bastian et al., 2017[138]; Dickinson et al., 2012[139]; Miller et al., 2011[140]; Farmer et al., 2011[141]; Farmer, Chancellor and Fischer, 2011[142]).
A minimum payment covers the farmers’ compliance costs with the scheme. These are comprised of the income forgone from practice adoption (opportunity costs) and the farmers’ private transaction costs (Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Falconer, 2000[43]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Engel, Pagiola and Wunder, 2008[143]; Mettepenningen et al., 2013[57]). Several authors point out that payments solely based on opportunity costs without transaction costs are insufficient (Wünscher and Engel, 2012[144]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]; Falconer, 2000[43]). Likewise, payments should account for possible shifts in opportunity costs or market prices over time (Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Niens and Marggraf, 2010[145]; Russi et al., 2016[146]).
The alternative remuneration method is to link payments to the social value of the environmental benefit that has been created (Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Hanley and White, 2013[35]; Engel, 2016[11]). Payment based on the value of environmental benefits is particularly relevant for the result-based payment schemes, where the achievement of environmental results provides the basis for payments. However, monetary valuation (social valuation) of environmental results is challenging and even for result-based schemes in which the payment is linked to the quantity or quality of the environmental result, the payment calculation may still be based on income foregone and extra costs incurred (Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Lankoski, 2016[5]).
Many studies show that farmers request higher payments for accepting restrictive contracts and reduced flexibility. Ruto and Garrod (2009[81]) stated that farmers request greater financial incentives for lower flexibility. Espinosa-Goded, Barreiro-Hurlé and Ruto (2010[37]) showed that higher payments increased farmers’ willingness to participate in schemes that required a change in farm management practices. Multiple studies confirm that lower payments were needed for less rigid contracts in terms of management prescriptions, contract length and paperwork involved (Espinosa-Goded, Barreiro-Hurlé and Ruto, 2010[37]; Ruto and Garrod, 2009[81]; Christensen et al., 2011[147]; Lastra-Bravo et al., 2015[56]; Breustedt, Schulz and Latacz-Lohmann, 2013[70]).
Allowing for more flexibility in management practices lowers the remuneration needed as farmers can select the least-cost practices for themselves and therefore increased flexibility can decrease overall budgetary costs. Result-based payments provide more flexibility in this regard as farmers can more freely choose the practices to attain the desired environmental result (Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Matzdorf and Lorenz, 2010[95]; Zabel and Roe, 2009[91]; Schilizzi, Breustedt and Latacz-Lohmann, 2011[148]; Matzdorf, 2004[83]; Schilizzi and Latacz-Lohmann, 2016[149]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). Furthermore, higher flexibility can reduce farmers’ compliance costs providing an incentive to identify the most efficient options (Matzdorf and Lorenz, 2010[95]; Weinberg and Claassen, 2006[131]; Wätzold and Schwerdtner, 2005[150]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]).
On the other hand, result-based schemes expose farmers to higher uncertainty of payments and therefore may necessitate risk premiums.3 If these risk premiums are higher than the compensation needed for reduced flexibility, a practice-based scheme might reduce the needed payment level (Schilizzi, Breustedt and Latacz-Lohmann, 2011[148]; Schilizzi and Latacz-Lohmann, 2016[149]).
Short-term contracts are the preferred option by farmers giving them flexibility on their farm management in the future (Engel, 2016[11]; Balderas Torres et al., 2013[120]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Miller et al., 2011[140]). This is especially relevant for practice-based schemes, where farmers value the option to change management practices when the contracts expire (Ruto and Garrod, 2009[81]; Lütz and Bastian, 2002[151]; Pasquini et al., 2009[152]). Shorter commitments allow farmers to stay responsive to changes in future market conditions, which might affect their opportunity costs (Engel, 2016[11]; Niens and Marggraf, 2010[145]; Russi et al., 2016[146]). Furthermore, short contracts allow trying out the policy for both the farmer and the implementing agency, if the scheme is in its initial stages (Engel, 2016[11]; Christensen et al., 2011[147]).
Some environmental objectives might require long-term commitments, calling for longer contracts, such as biodiversity conservation (Ruto and Garrod, 2009[81]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]). Long-term contracts can assure long-term provision of the environmental service and can help to assure conditionality (Engel, 2016[11]). For result-based schemes long-term contracts are beneficial, since the rationale of result-based payments is that farmers build up knowledge and develop new skills and innovation over time (Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; Baumgärtner and Hartmann, 2001[97]; Wittig, Kemmermann and Zacharias, 2006[31]). The aforementioned inherent risk of result-based schemes may also decline with increasing experience (Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; Casey and Boody, 2007[87]; Wätzold and Drechsler, 2005[90]). Additionally, it might take time until environmental outcomes can be observed (Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Hasund, 2013[153]). Therefore scheme success might be increased with long-term contracts (Mccracken et al., 2015[154]; Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013[155]).
Uniform fixed payment is currently the most commonly used option for agri-environmental schemes (Engel, 2016[11]; Latacz-Lohmann and Schilizzi, 2005[156]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Schilizzi, Breustedt and Latacz-Lohmann, 2011[148]). Its advantage is easier implementation and thus smaller transaction costs due to lower information needs (OECD, 2007[49]). If environmental benefits and compliance costs are relatively homogeneous among farmers and can be reasonably estimated, uniform payments are advisable (Mills et al., 2012[51]; Lankoski, 2016[5]).
Conversely, if compliance costs or environmental benefits differ largely among participants, uniform payments fail to account for this heterogeneity (OECD, 2007[49]; Latacz-Lohmann and Breustedt, 2019[157]; Hasund, 2013[153]; OECD, 2010[1]; Lankoski, 2016[5]), leading to overcompensation of farmers with low compliance costs (Groth, 2005[158]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Armsworth et al., 2012[44]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; OECD, 2010[1]), while farmers with high compliance costs, who could potentially deliver large environmental benefits, will not enter into the scheme, since they would be undercompensated (Groth, 2005[158]; Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]).
Under heterogeneous conditions, uniform payments therefore reduce the budgetary cost-effectiveness of the scheme due to high information rents (an overcompensation of a farmer’s income forgone and extra costs incurred) for low compliance cost farmers and adverse selection (Armsworth et al., 2012[44]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]; Holm-Mueller, Radke and Weis, 2002[159]; OECD, 2010[1]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). The choice between standardised and less costly fixed payments and more complex differentiated payments hence depends on the heterogeneity among farms regarding compliance costs and environmental benefits (OECD, 2007[49]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Wätzold and Schwerdtner, 2005[150]).
In contexts with high variability among farmers, payments can be differentiated, either on the basis of compliance costs or environmental benefits (Hanley and White, 2013[35]). Numerous authors have confirmed increased environmental effectiveness and cost-effectiveness with differentiated payments (Engel, 2016[11]; Porras et al., 2011[127]; Ezzine-De-Blas et al., 2016[160]; Groth, 2005[158]; Wünscher, Engel and Wunder, 2008[41]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). However, differentiated payments require more information than uniform payments and thus have higher transaction costs that reduce the potential cost-effectiveness gains from payment differentiation. (Engel, 2016[11]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Wätzold and Schwerdtner, 2005[150]; OECD, 2010[1]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). Another concern is that differentiated payments might be perceived as unfair by policymakers and farmers (Latacz-Lohmann and Schilizzi, 2005[156]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Holm-Müller and Hilden, 2004[161]).
Differentiated payments based on compliance costs require information on farmers’ compliance costs and farmers might not have incentives to reveal their true costs. This information asymmetry reduces the cost-effectiveness of the agri-environmental schemes (Engel, 2016[11]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; OECD, 2007[49]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Latacz-Lohmann and Breustedt, 2019[157]; Cooper, Hart and Baldock, 2009[162]; Canton, De Cara and Jayet, 2009[163]). One mechanism to overcome the asymmetric information problem are self-selection contracts. The implementing agency offers different contract types, which farmers choose depending on their own characteristics and hence reveal their preferences and compliance costs (Wu and Babcock, 1996[164]; Ozanne and White, 2007[165]; OECD, 2010[1]). Another mechanism to overcome information asymmetry is bidding mechanisms such as auctions, which have already been used in practice, for example, in the Conservation Reserve Program in the United States (Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]) and in the Victorian Bush Tender Trial (Cocklin, Mautner and Dibden, 2007[166]; Stoneham et al., 2003[167]; Vukina, Levy and Marra, 2006[168]; OECD, 2010[1]).
Through competitive bidding for agri-environmental contracts, farmers reveal their compliance costs, which reduces information rents and overcompensation and hence increases budgetary cost-effectiveness (Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Costedoat et al., 2016[169]; Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Boxall, Perger and Weber, 2013[170]; Stoneham et al., 2003[167]; Schillizzi and Latacz-Lohmann, 2007[171]; Glebe, 2008[172]).
In various studies auctions outperform fixed uniform payments with cost-effectiveness gains between 16% – 315% (without transaction costs) (Latacz-Lohmann and Schilizzi, 2005[156]). The gains in budgetary cost-effectiveness of auctions, however, are highly dependent on the magnitude of additional transaction costs relative to more simple payment designs (Glebe, 2008[172]; OECD, 2010[1]; Lankoski, 2016[5]). Lankoski (2016[5]) incorporates transaction costs of different payments designs (uniform payment, differentiated payments and auctions) for budgetary cost-effectiveness analysis of payments promoting biodiversity enhancement in farmland and finds that auctions and differentiated payments perform better than uniform payment even when transaction costs are accounted for (cost-effectiveness gain is 16% for auction and 5% for differentiated payment).
Following Lankoski (2016[5]) the relative performance of different payment designs, from uniform payments to results-based payments, depends on the extent to which opportunity costs and environmental quality4 vary across participants as illustrated in Table 2.4. Uniform payment works well when both opportunity costs and environmental quality are homogenous. When opportunity costs vary but environmental quality is homogenous then differentiated payment on the basis of costs would perform better and be fairer than uniform payment. In this case, an auction system would also perform well, but differentiated payment would probably be an easier and more flexible system when opportunity costs are reasonably well known. When environmental quality varies, the added value of auction systems and other targeting mechanisms (results-based or differentiated payments) increases. In these cases, auctions work well when the number of potential participants (bidders) is large, and results-based payment would be best suited for situations where the number of participants is low. When environmental quality varies, efficiency requires that auction and other mechanisms employ an environmental scoring system to address environmental heterogeneity, e.g. use of environmental benefit index. Also, policy-related transaction costs affect the efficiency of alternative payment types and thus auctions may be preferred to results-based schemes when potential pool of participants is large.
Table 2.4. Suitability of different payment types under homogenous and heterogeneous spatial conditions
Environmental quality |
Opportunity costs |
|
---|---|---|
Homogenous |
Heterogeneous |
|
Homogenous |
Uniform payment (N, n) |
Differentiated payment-cc (N, n) |
Heterogeneous |
Differentiated payment-eb (N,n) Auction-eb (N) Results-based payment-eb (n) |
Differentiated payment–cc and eb (N,n) Auction–cc and eb (N) Results-based payment–cc and eb (n) |
Note: N = works well with large number of participants; n = suitable for small number of participants; cc = differentiated on the basis of compliance costs; eb = differentiated on the basis of environmental benefits.
Source: Lankoski (2016[5]).
Conditionality and enforcement
Achieving strong conditionality means that farmers participating in an agri-environmental schemes receive remuneration if and only if they actually deliver the agreed action, practice, performance, or result as specified in their contract (Hardelin and Lankoski, 2018[6]; Engel, Pagiola and Wunder, 2008[143]; OECD, 2007[49]; Rojas and Aylward, 2003[173]). This assures that the payments are spent for actual environmental improvements, or actions leading to those improvements, and that the policy is cost-effective. Monitoring and controls are key elements to guarantee conditionality and increase compliance (Engel, Pagiola and Wunder, 2008[143]; OECD, 2007[49]; Porras et al., 2011[127]; Naeem et al., 2015[128]; Grammatikopoulou, 2016[174]).
The feasibility of monitoring and control of the measures may be challenging and comes with considerable costs (Berkhout, Doorn and Schrijver, 2018[135]; Claassen, Cattaneo and Johansson, 2008[46]; Chaplin, 2018[175]; Schwarz et al., 2008[22]). Porras et al. (2011[127]) state that if a practice-based scheme is based on easily observable land-use measures then it probably has lower monitoring costs than results-based schemes.
Monitoring costs depend on the environmental objective and its measurability. Some environmental goals are difficult to quantify and to measure, and thus quantified measurements for environmental performance are lacking (Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]; Moxey and White, 2014[33]; Kaiser et al., 2010[176]; Burton and Schwarz, 2013[55]; White and Sadler, 2012[32]; Matzdorf, Kaiser and Rohner, 2008[24]). When it is impossible to define clear indicators or when monitoring of results is more costly than monitoring of practices, practice-based payments are easier to enforce and can be more appropriate (Herzon et al., 2018[21]; Hanley and White, 2013[35]; Allen et al., 2014[20]; Börner et al., 2017[19]).
Moral hazard is a concern for agri-environmental payments. Farmers might have incentives to cheat, receiving the compensation without implementing the required practices and thus incurring the full compliance costs for their commitment. This is particularly the case for farmers with high compliance costs, since their pay-off for cheating is higher than for other farmers (Latacz-Lohmann and Schilizzi, 2005[156]; OECD, 2010[1]).
Controls and monitoring can only be effective if non-compliance is detected and penalised (OECD, 2007[49]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]). Sanctions usually include the cancellation of future payments or sometimes past payments have to be paid back (Brouwer, Tesfaye and Pauw, 2011[52]; Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; Engel, 2016[11]). While the rationale for fines is to achieve high compliance levels, excessive penalties can actually reduce compliance or participation because farmers might perceive them as demotivating (Engel, 2016[11]; Börner et al., 2017[19]; Falk and Kosfeld, 2006[177]; Vollan, 2008[178]). Herodes (2008[179]) finds that unclear control criteria entail widespread reluctance among farmers for scheme participation. Thus, it is important to have clear control criteria that are linked to farmer-controlled variables to enhance scheme participation.
Successful enforcement requires setting the levels of the following elements appropriately: 1) intensity of monitoring, 2) level of sanctions, 3) stringency of compliance requirements, and 4) level of agri-environmental payments (Latacz-Lohmann, 1998[180]). Several authors have derived optimal monitoring and sanction strategies in the context of agricultural and agri-environmental policies (Choe and Fraser, 1999[181]; Ozanne, Hogan and Colman, 2001[182]; Kampas and White, 2003[183]; Fraser, 2002[184]).
In practice, monitoring rates for agri-environmental payments are relatively low in developed countries and lie between 3% and 5% (Wunder, Engel and Pagiola, 2008[18]; OECD, 2010[1]). Many programmes lack effective enforcement strategies (Hart and Latacz-Lohmann, 2005[185]), which could reduce environmental effectiveness (Ezzine-De-Blas et al., 2016[160]). Yet, enforcement is a crucial element for conditionality and hence an important driver for the cost-effectiveness of the policy.
2.3. Policy Spectrum Framework: Assessment of payment design options according to key dimensions of cost-effectiveness
Table 2.5 provides an assessment of policy design options covered by the Framework. This assessment is based on the literature review and Secretariat’s judgement. It does not aim to identify the single “best” policy design (no “one size fits all” approach), but rather discusses advantages and disadvantages of different options, presenting evidence from literature review, policy simulations and economic experiment on performance of different policy options according to the key criteria (primarily cost-effectiveness, but also other criteria as discussed above, where warranted). In Table 2.5, uniform and targeted practice-based payments are discussed in the same column, since both are practice-based options. Aggregate or landscape-level results-based payment is not separately presented it represents a special case of results-based payment.
Table 2.5. Qualitative assessment of payment design options from a cost-effectiveness viewpoint
Policy design element |
Uniform or targeted practice-based payment |
Performance-based payment |
Result-based payment |
Hybrid payment |
---|---|---|---|---|
Quantifiable policy objectives |
May be preferred option only when environmental performance or results are very difficult or costly to measure. Works if practices are highly correlated with environmental performance or results and quantitative targets are set e.g. for acreage or number of participants. |
Improves cost-effectiveness if suitable environmental performance proxies are available, such as environmental benefit indices and nutrient balances. Suitable option if direct environmental results cannot be measured. |
Improves cost-effectiveness if environmental results can be reliably measured or suitable indicator approaches are available, for example, in the context of biodiversity. |
Improves cost-effectiveness relative to pure practice-based approach. |
Targeting |
Uniform practice-based payment has poor cost-effectiveness when there is spatial heterogeneity in compliance costs and/or environmental benefits. Targeted (whether cost-targeting or benefit targeting or benefit-cost targeting) practice-based payment improves cost-effectiveness relative to uniform payment. |
Improves cost-effectiveness by allowing spatial targeting based on environmental proxies (e.g. nutrient surplus or environmental benefit index value). |
Improves cost-effectiveness by allowing spatial targeting based on environmental benefits or benefit-cost ratios. |
Improves cost-effectiveness by allowing spatial targeting based on environmental benefits or benefit-cost ratios. |
Tailoring |
Uniform payment rate works only when compliance costs are homogeneous among farmers, which is rarely the case. Poor cost-effectiveness due to overcompensation of compliance costs to low-cost farmers (information rent). High-cost farmers with potentially high environmental benefits do not participate (adverse selection). |
Payment rate can be tailored, for example, by providing differentiated payment rate on the basis of environmental performance. Combination of competitive bidding (auctions) and environmental benefit index would allow benefit-cost targeting that highly improves cost-effectiveness as auction mechanism reduces information rent and environmental benefit index targets high benefit sites. |
Improves cost-effectiveness as payment rate can be tailored to reflect environmental results achieved. The uncertainties associated with the achievement of the results may require a risk premium for risk-averse farmers, which reduces budgetary cost-effectiveness. |
Payment rate can be tailored according to compliance costs of adopting the practices and environmental results achieved. Reduces the financial risk for farmers as compliance costs are covered for practice adoption. |
Additionality |
Option only when environmental performance or results are very difficult or costly to measure. Can provide additionality, if practices are highly correlated with environmental performance or results, and practices would not have been adopted without payment. |
Enables payment for the environmental performance improvement and thus increases environmental effectiveness, additionality and budgetary cost-effectiveness. |
Result-based payment directly linked payment to environmental results and hence has the potential to achieve high additionality, environmental effectiveness and budgetary cost-effectiveness. However, if payment is linked to maintaining already achieved results then additionality is low. |
Bonus payment (result-based payment) is directly linked to environmental results so there is high potential for additionality. |
Enforcement |
Monitoring and enforcement should be relatively easy for observable measures, such as land use and land cover based measures. But, is more difficult for unobservable measures, such as chemical fertiliser, pesticide and manure application intensity. May be preferred option If practices can be monitored and enforced more easily and with much lower transaction costs than performance-based or results-based payments. |
If environmental performance improvements can be clearly defined and monitored then performance-based payments can be beneficial. However, this requires suitable environmental performance indicators that may be lacking for some environmental objectives. When it is impossible to define clear performance indicators or when monitoring of performance is more costly than monitoring of practices, practice-based payments may be easier to enforce and can be more appropriate |
If results can be clearly defined and monitored then result-based payments can be beneficial. However, this requires suitable and reliable indicator approaches that may be lacking for some environmental objectives. When it is impossible to define clear indicators for results or when monitoring of results is more costly than monitoring of practices, practice-based payments may be easier to enforce and can be more appropriate |
May be beneficial if practices are easily observed, monitored and enforced. |
Transaction costs |
Transaction costs (both public and private) should be relatively low for uniform practice-based payment and this is especially the case when practices are relatively easy to observe, monitor and enforce (e.g. land use based measures). Targeted uniform payments will increase transaction costs somewhat as information is required, for example, on spatial variation of potential environmental benefits of practice adoption. |
Differentiated payments and bidding mechanisms have higher transaction costs than uniform payments due to higher information needs, including information related to spatial variation of environmental benefits and/or compliance costs. Also the development of suitable environmental performance indicators that can be tailored to local circumstances adds complexity and transaction costs. |
Transaction costs can be reduced if reliable result indicators based on up-to-date data are readily available and if these are relatively easy to understand and measure by farmers, which allows self-monitoring by farmers. |
Transaction costs may be high as both practices and results need to monitored and enforced. |
Behavioural factors |
Provides rigid management proscriptions without farm-specific flexibility that are not necessarily the least-cost ways to achieve environmental objectives. Does not provide incentives for innovation. Financial risk lower than with the performance-based and the results-based payments, especially when environmental performance and results are dependent on external factors (e.g. weather) outside of the farmers’ control. |
Increases flexibility and fosters innovation, which promotes the least cost achievement of the environmental performance targets. If environmental performance scores are dependent on factors outside of farmers’ control then may increase financial risk relative to the practice-based payment. |
Increases flexibility and foster innovation, which promotes the least cost achievement of the environmental results. Relative to the practice-based payments the result-based payments tend to increase social networking, knowledge sharing and intrinsic motivation for environmental conservation. However, relative to practice-based payments the results-based payments may increase financial risk for farmers and thus may increase a risk premium required by risk-averse farmers. |
Relative to the pure results-based payment decreases flexibility and innovation and thus potentially cost-effectiveness. On the other hand is less risky option to risk-averse farmers which may increase acceptance and participation. |
References
[72] Adams, V., R. Pressey and N. Stoeckl (2014), “Estimating Landholders’ Probability of Participating in a Stewardship Program, and the Implications for Spatial Conservation Priorities”, PLoS ONE, Vol. 9/6, p. 97941, https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0097941.
[186] Adams, V., R. Pressey and N. Stoeckl (2012), “Estimating land and conservation management costs: The first step in designing a stewardship program for the Northern Territory”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 148/1, pp. 44-53, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2012.01.064.
[20] Allen, B. et al. (2014), Biodiversity protection through results based remuneration of ecological achievement, Institute for European Environmental Policy, London, http://www.ieep.eu.
[187] Alló, M., M. Loureiro and E. Iglesias (2015), “Farmers’ Preferences and Social Capital Regarding Agri-environmental Schemes to Protect Birds”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 66/3, pp. 672-689, https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12104.
[130] Alpizar, F. et al. (2013), “Effects of Exclusion from a Conservation Policy: Negative Behavioral Spillovers from Targeted Incentives”, Duke Environmental and Energy Economics Working Paper Series EE 13-06, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2467666.
[86] Andeltová, L. (2018), Action-based and outcome-based payments for environmental services : An experimental auction for tree planting contracts in Kenya, Landwirtschaftlichen Fakultät der Rheinischen Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität Bonn.
[129] Angelsen, A. and S. Wertz-Kanounnikoff (2008), What are the Key Design Issues for REDD and the Criteria for Assessing Options?, Ed. by A. Angelsen, CIFOR, Bogor, Indonesia.
[47] Arbuckle, J. (2013), “Farmer Attitudes toward Proactive Targeting of Agricultural Conservation Programs”, Society and Natural Resources, Vol. 26/6, pp. 625-641, https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920.2012.671450.
[44] Armsworth, P. et al. (2012), “The cost of policy simplification in conservation incentive programs”, Ecology Letters, Vol. 15/5, pp. 406-414, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1461-0248.2012.01747.x.
[219] Arnaud, S. et al. (2007), Consolidated report on farm surveys ITAES WP8 Final report, https://prodinra.inra.fr/record/39266.
[69] Aviron, S. et al. (2005), “Carabid assemblages in agricultural landscapes: Impacts of habitat features, landscape context at different spatial scales and farming intensity”, Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment, Vol. 108/3, pp. 205-217, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agee.2005.02.004.
[42] Balana, B., A. Vinten and B. Slee (2011), “A review on cost-effectiveness analysis of agri-environmental measures related to the EU WFD: Key issues, methods, and applications”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 70/6, pp. 1021-1031, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.12.020.
[120] Balderas Torres, A. et al. (2013), “Payments for ecosystem services and rural development: Landowners’ preferences and potential participation in western Mexico”, Ecosystem Services, Vol. 6, pp. 72-81.
[40] Bartkowski, B. et al. (2018), “Institutional economics of agricultural soil ecosystem services”, Sustainability (Switzerland), Vol. 10/7, https://doi.org/10.3390/su10072447.
[48] Barton, D. et al. (2003), Spatial Prioritisation of Environmental Service Payments for Biodiversity Protection, NIVA (Norwegian Institute for Water Research), Norway.
[138] Bastian, C. et al. (2017), “Landowner and land trust agent preferences for conservation easements: Implications for sustainable land uses and landscapes”, Landscape and Urban Planning, Vol. 157, pp. 1-13, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landurbplan.2016.05.030.
[7] Batáry, P. et al. (2015), “The role of agri-environment schemes in conservation and environmental management”, Conservation Biology, Vol. 29/4, pp. 1006–1016, https://doi.org/10.1111/cobi.12536.
[97] Baumgärtner, J. and J. Hartmann (2001), “The design and implementation of sustainable plant diversity conservation program for alpine meadows”, Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics, Vol. 14, pp. 67-83.
[112] Beckmann, V., J. Eggers and E. Mettepenningen (2009), “Deciding how to decide on agri-environmental schemes: the political economy of subsidiarity, decentralisation and participation in the European Union”, Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, Vol. 52/2, pp. 689-716.
[188] Beharry-Borg, N. et al. (2013), “Evaluating farmers’ likely participation in a payment programme for water quality protection in the UK uplands”, Regional Environmental Change, Vol. 13/3, pp. 633-647, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10113-012-0282-9.
[189] Bennett, M., Y. Gong and R. Scarpa (2018), “Hungry Birds and Angry Farmers: Using Choice Experiments to Assess “Eco-compensation” for Coastal Wetlands Protection in China”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 154, pp. 71-87, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.07.016.
[135] Berkhout, P., A. Doorn and R. Schrijver (2018), Targeted payments for services delivered by farmers : possible approaches, Wageningen Economic Research, Wageningen, https://doi.org/10.18174/451594.
[39] Berry, J. et al. (2005), “Applying spatial analysis for precision conservation across the landscape”, Journal of Soil Water Conservation, Vol. 60/6, pp. 363-370.
[23] Bertke, E., S. Klimek and B. Wittig (2008), “Developing result-orientated payment schemes for environmental services in grasslands: Results from two case studies in north-western germany”, Biodiversity, Vol. 9/1-2, pp. 91-95, https://doi.org/10.1080/14888386.2008.9712893.
[99] Best, H. (2010), “Environmental concern and the adoption of organic agriculture”, Society & Natural Resources, Vol. 23/5, pp. 451-468, https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920802178206.
[115] Bocquého, G., F. Jacquet and A. Reynaud (2014), “Expected utility or prospect theory maximisers? Assessing farmers’ risk behaviour from field-experiment data”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 41/1, pp. 135-172.
[19] Börner, J. et al. (2017), “The Effectiveness of Payments for Environmental Services”, World Development, Vol. 96, pp. 359-374, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.03.020.
[134] Bosch, D. et al. (2013), “Perverse Incentives with Pay for Performance: Cover Crops in the Chesapeake Bay Watershed”, Agricultural and Resource Economics Review, Vol. 42/3.
[170] Boxall, P., O. Perger and M. Weber (2013), “Reverse auctions for agri-environmental improvements: Bid-selection rules and pricing for beneficial management practice adoption”, Canadian Public Policy, Vol. 39/SUPPL.2, https://doi.org/10.3138/CPP.39.Supplement2.S23.
[84] Bräuer, I., R. Müssner and K. Marsden (2006), The Use of Market Incentives to Preserve Biodiversity The Use of Market Incentives to Preserve Biodiversity, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/238734624.
[190] Breustedt, G., N. Schulz and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2013), “Ermittlung der Teilnahmebereitschaft an Vertragsnaturschutz-programmen und der dafür notwendigen Ausgleichszahlungen mit Hilfe eines Discrete-Choice-Experimentes”, GJAE, Vol. 62/4, http://www.gjae-online.de.
[70] Breustedt, G., N. Schulz and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2013), “Factors affecting participation and compensation requirements in AES - insights from a Discrete Choice Experiment”, German Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 62/4, pp. 244 - 258.
[38] Broch, S. et al. (2013), “Farmers’ willingness to provide ecosystem services and effects of their spatial distribution”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 92, pp. 78-86, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.12.017.
[191] Brouwer, R., N. Lienhoop and F. Oosterhuis (2015), “Incentivizing afforestation agreements: Institutional-economic conditions and motivational drivers”, Journal of Forest Economics, Vol. 21/4, pp. 205-222, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2015.09.003.
[52] Brouwer, R., A. Tesfaye and P. Pauw (2011), “Meta-analysis of institutional-economic factors explaining the environmental performance of payments for watershed services”, Environmental Conservation, Vol. 38/4, pp. 380-392, https://doi.org/10.1017/S0376892911000543.
[74] Burton, R., C. Kuczera and G. Schwarz (2008), “Exploring Farmers’ Cultural Resistance to Voluntary Agri-environmental Schemes”, Sociologia Ruralis, Vol. 48/1.
[66] Burton, R. and U. Paragahawewa (2011), “Creating culturally sustainable agri-environmental schemes”, Journal of Rural Studies, Vol. 27/1, pp. 95-104, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2010.11.001.
[55] Burton, R. and G. Schwarz (2013), “Result-oriented agri-environmental schemes in Europe and their potential for promoting behavioural change”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 30, pp. 628-641, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.05.002.
[163] Canton, J., S. De Cara and P. Jayet (2009), “Agri-environmental schemes: Adverse selection, information structure and delegation”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 68/7, pp. 2114-2121, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.02.007.
[111] Capitanio, F., E. Adinolfi and G. Malorgio (2011), “What explains farmers participation in Rural Development Policy in Italian southern region”, New Medit, Vol. 10/4, pp. 19-24.
[132] Casasola, F. et al. (2009), “Implementación de sistemas silvopastoriles y el pago de servicios ambientales en Esparza, Costa Rica: una herramienta para la adaptación al cambio climático en fincas ganaderas”, in Sepúlveda, C. and M. Ibrahim (eds.), Políticas y sistemas de incentivos para el fomento y adopción de buenas prácticas agrícolas: como una medida para adaptación al cambio climático en América Central.
[87] Casey, F. and G. Boody (2007), An Assessment of Performance-Based Indicators and Payments for Resource Conservation on Agricultural Lands, Report for the Multiple Benefits of Agriculture Initiative.
[124] Chabé-Ferret, S. and J. Subervie (2013), “How much green for the buck? Estimating additional and windfall effects of French agro-environmental schemes by DID-matching”, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 65/1, pp. 12-27.
[175] Chaplin, S. (2018), Developing Payment by Results approaches for agri-environment schemes-experience from a pilot project in England, Natural England, York, UK, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/325573800.
[107] Chen, X. et al. (2009), “Linking social norms to efficient conservation investment in payments for ecosystem services.”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, Vol. 106/28, pp. 11812-7, https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0809980106.
[92] Chèze, B., M. David and V. Martinet (2017), Farmers’ motivations to reduce their use of pesticides: a choice experiment analysis in France, UMR Economie Publique, INRA-AgroParisTech, http://faere.fr/pub/Conf2017/FAERE2017_Cheze.pdf.
[181] Choe, C. and I. Fraser (1999), “Compliance Monitoring and Agri- Environmental Policy”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 50.
[147] Christensen, T. et al. (2011), “Determinants of farmers’ willingness to participate in subsidy schemes for pesticide-free buffer zones-A choice experiment study”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 70/8, pp. 1558-1564, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.03.021.
[46] Claassen, R., A. Cattaneo and R. Johansson (2008), “Cost-effective design of agri-environmental payment programs: U.S. experience in theory and practice”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65/4, pp. 737-752, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.032.
[125] Claassen, R., E. Duquette and D. Smith (2018), “Additionality in U.S. Agricultural Conservation Prgrams”, Land Economics, Vol. 94/1, pp. 19-35, https://doi.org/10.3368/le.94.1.19.
[166] Cocklin, C., N. Mautner and J. Dibden (2007), “Public policy, private landholders: Perspectives on policy mechanisms for sustainable land management”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 85/4, pp. 986-998, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2006.11.009.
[8] Coderoni, S. and R. Esposti (2018), “CAP payments and agricultural GHG emissions in Italy. A farm-level assessment”, Science of The Total Environment, Vol. 627, pp. 427-437, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.SCITOTENV.2018.01.197.
[123] Colen, L. et al. (2016), “Economic experiments as a tool for agricultural policy evaluation: insights from the European CAP”, Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue Canadienne d’agroeconomie, Vol. 64/4, pp. 667-694, https://doi.org/10.1111/cjag.12107.
[136] Colombo, S. and B. Rocamora-Montiel (2018), “Result-oriented agri-environmental climate schemes as a means of promoting climate change mitigation in olive growing”, Outlook on Agriculture, Vol. 47/2, pp. 141-149, https://doi.org/10.1177/0030727018770931.
[162] Cooper, T., K. Hart and D. Baldock (2009), The Provision of Public Goods Through Agriculture in the European Union, Report Prepared for DG Agriculture and Rural Development, Contract No 30-CE-0233091 /00-28. Institute for European Environmental Policy.
[169] Costedoat, S. et al. (2016), “Cash only? Unveiling preferences for a PES contract through a choice experiment in Chiapas, Mexico”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 58, pp. 302-317, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2016.07.023.
[62] Cranford, M. (2014), Positive incentives for ecosystem services, Department of Geography and Environment. London School of Economics.
[101] Cullen, P. et al. (2018), “Agri-Environment Scheme Design: Past Lessons and Future Suggestions”, EuroChoices, Vol. 17/3, pp. 26-30, https://doi.org/10.1111/1746-692X.12187.
[68] Dahms, H. et al. (2010), “Contrasting diversity patterns of epigeic arthropods between grasslands of high and low agronomic potential”, Basic and Applied Ecology, Vol. 11/1, pp. 6-14, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.baae.2009.06.004.
[9] Dal Ferro, N. et al. (2018), “How to enhance crop production and nitrogen fluxes? A result-oriented scheme to evaluate best agri-environmental measures in Veneto Region, Italy”, Archives of Agronomy and Soil Science, Vol. 64/11, pp. 1518-1533, https://doi.org/10.1080/03650340.2018.1442573.
[102] Damianos, D. and N. Giannakopoulos (2002), “Farmers’ participation in agri-environmental schemes in Greece”, British Food Journal, Vol. 104, pp. 261-273, https://doi.org/10.1108/00070700210425705.
[71] Danne, M. and O. Musshoff (2017), “Analysis of farmers’ willingness to participate in pasture grazing programs: Results from a discrete choice experiment with German dairy farmers”, Journal of Dairy Science, Vol. 100/9, pp. 7569-7580, https://doi.org/10.3168/jds.2017-12756.
[79] Darnhofer, I. et al. (2017), “Preserving permanent mountain grasslands in Western Europe: Why are promising approaches not implemented more widely?”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 68, pp. 306-315, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.08.005.
[103] Defrancesco, E. et al. (2008), “Factors affecting farmers’ participation in agri-environmental measures: a Northern Italian perspective.”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 59/1, pp. 114-131.
[104] D’Emden, F., R. Llewellyn and M. Burton (2008), “Factors influencing adoption of conservation tillage in Australian cropping regions”, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Vol. 52/2, pp. 169-182, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2008.00409.x.
[13] Dessart, F., J. Barreiro-Hurlé and R. van Bavel (2019), “Behavioural factors affecting the adoption of sustainable farming practices: a policy-oriented review”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 46/3, pp. 417-471, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbz019.
[192] Dhingra, N. et al. (2015), Importance of Contract Attributes on Conservation Reserve Program Enrollment Decisions in the Prairie Pothole Region, http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/205712/2/CRP%20Paper%20for%20AAEA%20Meetings.pdf (accessed on 13 February 2019).
[139] Dickinson, B. et al. (2012), “Estimated participation in U.S. carbon sequestration programs: a study of NIPF landowners in Massachusetts”, Journal of Forest Economics, Vol. 18, pp. 36-46.
[34] Diekmann, M. (2003), “Species indicator values as an important tool in applied plant ecology - a review”, Basic and Applied Ecology, Vol. 4, pp. 493-506, http://www.urbanfischer.de/journals/baecol.
[64] Dietz, T., E. Ostrom and P. Stern (2003), “The struggle to govern the commons”, Science, Vol. 302, pp. 1907-1912.
[65] Dobbs, T. and J. Pretty (2008), “Case study of agri-environmental payments: the United Kingdom”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65, pp. 765-775.
[114] Doyle, J. (2012), “Survey of time preference, delay discounting models”, Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 8/2, pp. 116-135.
[121] Duquette, E., N. Higgins and J. Horowitz (2012), “Farmer discount rates: experimental evidence”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 64/2, pp. 451-456, http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aar067.
[106] Emery, S. and J. Franks (2012), “The potential for collaborative agri-environment schemes in England: Can a well-designed collaborative approach address farmers’ concerns with current schemes?”, Journal of Rural Studies, Vol. 28/3, pp. 218-231, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2012.02.004.
[11] Engel, S. (2016), “The Devil in the Detail: A Practical Guide on Designing Payments for Environmental Services”, International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 9/1-2, pp. 131-177, https://doi.org/10.1561/101.00000076.
[143] Engel, S., S. Pagiola and S. Wunder (2008), “Designing Payments for Environmental Services in Theory and Practice — An Overview of the Issues”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65, pp. 663-674.
[194] Espinosa-Goded, M. and J. Barreiro-Hurlé (2010), “Las preferencias discontinuas en los experimentos de elección: impacto en el cálculo de la prima de los programas agroambientales”, Economía Agraria y Recursos Naturales, Vol. 10/1, pp. 155-176.
[73] Espinosa-Goded, M., J. Barreiro-Hurlé and P. Dupraz (2013), “Identifying additional barriers in the adoption of agri-environmental schemes: The role of fixed costs”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 31, pp. 526-535, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.08.016.
[37] Espinosa-Goded, M., J. Barreiro-Hurlé and E. Ruto (2010), “What do farmers want from agri-environmental scheme design? A choice experiment approach”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 61/2, pp. 259-273, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.2010.00244.x.
[200] Etxano, I. et al. (2015), “A participatory integrated assessment approach for Natura 2000 network sites”, Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, Vol. 33/5, pp. 1207-1232, https://doi.org/10.1177/0263774x15612318.
[160] Ezzine-De-Blas, D. et al. (2016), “Global patterns in the implementation of payments for environmental services”, PLoS ONE, Vol. 11/3, https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0149847.
[43] Falconer, K. (2000), “Farm-level constraints on agri-environmental scheme participation: a transactional perspective”, Journal of Rural Studies, Vol. 16, pp. 379-394.
[177] Falk, A. and M. Kosfeld (2006), “The hidden costs of control”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 96/5, pp. 1611-1630.
[45] FAO (2007), “The State of Food and Agriculture. Payments for Environmental Services”, FAO Agriculture Series, FAO, Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome.
[142] Farmer, J., C. Chancellor and B. Fischer (2011), “Motivations for using conservation easements as a land protection mechanism: a mixed methods analysis”, Natural Areas Journal, Vol. 31/1, pp. 80-87, https://doi.org/10.3375/043.031.0109.
[141] Farmer, J. et al. (2011), “Motivations influencing the adoption of conservation easements”, Conservation Biology, Vol. 25/4, pp. 827-834, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1523-1739.2011.01686.x.
[137] Ferraro, P. (2008), “Asymmetric information and contract design for payments for environmental services”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65/4, pp. 810-821.
[126] Ferraro, P. and S. Pattanayak (2006), “Money for nothing? A call for empirical evaluation of biodiversity conservation investments”, PLOS Biology, Vol. 4/4.
[88] Ferraro, P. and R. Simpson (2002), “The cost-effectiveness of conservation payments”, Land Economics, Vol. 78, pp. 339-353.
[50] Franks, J. (2011), “The collective provision of environmental goods: A discussion of contractual issues”, Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, Vol. 54/5, pp. 637-660, https://doi.org/10.1080/09640568.2010.526380.
[195] Franzén, F., P. Dinnétz and M. Hammer (2016), “Factors affecting farmers’ willingness to participate in eutrophication mitigation — A case study of preferences for wetland creation in Sweden”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 130, pp. 8-15, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.05.019.
[184] Fraser, R. (2002), “Moral Hazard and Risk Management in Agrienvironmental Policy”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 53.
[105] Gillich, C. et al. (2019), “Combining choice modeling estimates and stochastic simulations to assess the potential of new crops—The case of lignocellulosic perennials in Southwestern Germany”, GCB Bioenergy, Vol. 11/1, pp. 289-303, https://doi.org/10.1111/gcbb.12550.
[172] Glebe, T. (2008), “Scoring two-dimensional bids: how cost-effective are agri-environmental auctions?”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 35/2, pp. 143-165.
[59] Goldman, R., B. Thompson and G. Daily (2007), “Institutional incentives for managing the landscape: Inducing cooperation for the production of ecosystem services”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 64/2, pp. 333-343.
[85] Gorddard, R., S. Whitten and A. Reeson (2008), When should biodiversity tenders contract on outcomes?, CSIRO Sustainable Ecosystems, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/23508008.
[174] Grammatikopoulou, I. (2016), Addressing the demand for and supply of ecosystem services in agriculture through market-based and target-based policy measures, Natural Resources Institute Finland (Luke), Helsinki, http://urn.fi/URN:ISBN:.
[196] Greiner, R. (2015), “Motivations and attitudes influence farmers’ willingness to participate in biodiversity conservation contracts”, Agricultural Systems, Vol. 137, pp. 154-165, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.AGSY.2015.04.005.
[197] Greiner, R., M. Bliemer and J. Ballweg (2014), “Design considerations of a choice experiment to estimate likely participation by north Australian pastoralists in contractual biodiversity conservation.”, Journal of Choice Modelling, Vol. 10, pp. 34-45, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.JOCM.2014.01.002.
[122] Grolleau, G., N. Mzoughi and S. Thoyer (2015), “Les incitations monétaires dans la politique agro-environnementale: peut-on faire mieux avec moins?”, Revue d’Etudes En Agriculture et Environnement, Vol. 96/02, pp. 251-257.
[158] Groth, M. (2005), “Auctions in an outcome-based payment scheme to reward ecological services in agriculture – Conception, implementation and results”, 45th Congress of the European Regional Science Association: "Land Use and Water Management in a Sustainable Network Society", 23-27 August 2005, Regional Science Association (ERSA), http://hdl.handle.net/10419/117492.
[15] Guerrero, S. (2021), “Characterising agri-environmental policies: Towards measuring their progress”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 155, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/41257e3c-en.
[35] Hanley, N. and B. White (2013), “Incentivizing the Provision of Ecosystem Services”, International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 7/3-4, pp. 299-331.
[116] Hardaker, J. and G. Lien (2010), “Probabilities for decision analysis in agriculture and rural resource economics: the need for a paradigm change”, Agricultural Systems, Vol. 103/6, pp. 345-350.
[6] Hardelin, J. and J. Lankoski (2018), “Land use and ecosystem services”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 114, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/c7ec938e-en.
[185] Hart, R. and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2005), “Combating moral hazard in agri-environmental schemes: A multiple-agent approach”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 32/1, pp. 75-91, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbi002.
[153] Hasund, K. (2013), “Indicator-based agri-environmental payments: A payment-by-result model for public goods with a Swedish application”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 30/1, pp. 223-233, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.03.011.
[76] Hermann, D., O. Mußhoff and K. Agethen (2016), “Investment behavior and status quo bias of conventional and organic hog farmers: an experimental approach”, Renewable Agriculture and Food Systems, Vol. 31/4, pp. 318-329, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1742170515000265.
[179] Herodes, M. (2008), Reflecting Environmental Land Use Needs into EU Policy: Preserving and Enhancing the Environmental Benefits of Unfarmed Features on EU Farmland. Case Study Report Sweden, Institute for European Environmental Policy, London.
[21] Herzon, I. et al. (2018), “Time to look for evidence: Results-based approach to biodiversity conservation on farmland in Europe”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 71, pp. 347-354, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.12.011.
[159] Holm-Mueller, K., V. Radke and J. Weis (2002), “Umweltfördermaßnahmen in der Landwirtschaft – Teilnehmerauswahl durch Ausschreibungen?”, Agrarwirtschaft, Vol. 51, pp. 112-120.
[161] Holm-Müller, K. and R. Hilden (2004), “Ausschreibung von Agrarumweltprogrammen am Beispiel der Grünlandextensivierung”, Schriften der Gesellschaft für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften des Landbaues e.V, Vol. 40, pp. 215-223.
[198] Hope, R., M. Borgoyary and C. Agarwal (2008), “Smallholder Preferences for Agri-environmental Change at the Bhoj Wetland, India”, Development Policy Review, Vol. 26/5, pp. 585-602.
[199] Hoyos, D. et al. (2012), “Valuing a Natura 2000 network site to inform land use options using a discrete choice experiment: An illustration from the Basque Country”, Journal of Forest Economics, Vol. 18/4, pp. 329-344, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2012.05.002.
[201] Hudson, D. and J. Lusk (2004), “Risk and Transactions Cost in Contracting: Results from a Choice-Based Experiment”, Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, Vol. 2/1, https://doi.org/10.2202/1542-0485.1046.
[202] Jaeck, M. and R. Lifran (2014), “Farmers’ Preferences for Production Practices: A Choice Experiment Study in the Rhone River Delta”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 65/1, pp. 112-130, https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12018.
[60] Jones, N. et al. (2009), “The influence of social capital on environmental policy instruments”, Environmental Politics, Vol. 18/4, pp. 595-611.
[203] Kaczan, D., B. Swallow and W. Adamowicz (2013), “Designing a payments for ecosystem services (PES) program to reduce deforestation in Tanzania: An assessment of payment approaches”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 95, pp. 20-30, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.07.011.
[117] Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979), “Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk”, Econometrica : Journal of the Econometric Society, Vol. 47/2, pp. 263-291, https://doi.org/10.2307/1914185.
[176] Kaiser, T. et al. (2010), “Validation of grassland indicator species selected for result-oriented agri-environmental schemes”, Biodiversity and Conservation, Vol. 19/5, pp. 1297-1314, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10531-009-9762-8.
[119] Kallas, Z., T. Serra and J. Gil (2010), “Farmers’ objectives as determinants of organic farming adoption: the case of Catalonian vineyard production”, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 41/5, pp. 409-423.
[183] Kampas, A. and B. White (2003), “Probabilistic Programming for Nitrate Pollution Control: Comparing Different Probabilistic Constraint Approximations”, European Journal of Operations Research, Vol. 147.
[27] Kleijn, D. et al. (2001), “Agri-environment schemes do not effectively protect biodiversity in Dutch agricultural landscapes”, Nature, Vol. 413, pp. 723-725.
[28] Kleijn, D. et al. (2004), “Ecological Effectiveness of Agri-Environment Schemes in Different Agricultural Landscapes in The Netherlands”, Conservation Biology, Vol. 18/3, pp. 775-786.
[80] Klimek, S. et al. (2008), “Rewarding farmers for delivering vascular plant diversity in managed grasslands: A transdisciplinary case-study approach”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 141/11, pp. 2888-2897, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2008.08.025.
[205] Kreye, M., D. Adams and H. Ober (2018), “Protecting Imperiled Wildlife Species on Private Lands: Forest Owner Values and Response to Government Interventions”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 149, pp. 254-264, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.03.016.
[204] Kreye, M. et al. (2017), “Creating Voluntary Payment Programs: Effective Program Design and Ranchers’ Willingness to Conserve Florida Panther Habitat”, Land Economics, Vol. 93/3, pp. 459-480.
[206] Kuhfuss, L. et al. (2016), “Nudging farmers to enrol land into agri-environmental schemes: The role of a collective bonus”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbv031.
[93] Kuminoff, N. and A. Wossink (2010), “Why isn’t more US farmland organic?”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 61/2, pp. 240-258, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.2009.00235.x.
[5] Lankoski, J. (2016), “Alternative Payment Approaches for Biodiversity Conservation in Agriculture”, OECD Food, Agriculture and Fisheries Papers, No. 93, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/5jm22p4ptg33-en.
[4] Lankoski, J. and M. Ollikainen (2003), “Agri-environmental externalities: a framework for designing targeted policies”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 30, pp. 51-75.
[100] Läpple, D. and T. Van Rensburg (2011), “Adoption of organic farming: Are there differences between early and late adoption?”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 70/7, pp. 1406–1414, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.03.002.
[56] Lastra-Bravo, X. et al. (2015), “What drives farmers’ participation in EU agri-environmental schemes?: Results from a qualitative meta-analysis”, Environmental Science and Policy, Vol. 54, pp. 1-9, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2015.06.002.
[180] Latacz-Lohmann, U. (1998), Moral hazard in agri-environmental schemes, Paper presented to the annual conference of the Agricultural Economics Society, 25-28 March.
[157] Latacz-Lohmann, U. and G. Breustedt (2019), “Using choice experiments to improve the design of agri-environmental schemes”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 46/3, pp. 495-528, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbz020.
[156] Latacz-Lohmann, U. and S. Schilizzi (2005), Auctions for conservation contracts: A review of the theoretical and empirical literature, Scottish Executive Environment and Rural Affairs Department.
[207] Layton, D. and J. Siikamäki (2009), “Payments for Ecosystem Services Programs: Predicting Landowner Enrollment and Opportunity Cost Using a Beta-Binomial Model”, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 44/3, pp. 415-439, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-009-9293-5.
[53] Le Coent, P. and S. Thoyer (2014), “Why pay for nothing? An experiment on a conditional subsidy scheme in a threshold public good game”, Economics Bulletin, Vol. 34/3, pp. 1976-1989, https://www.researchgate.net/publication/270508300.
[208] Lienhoop, N. and R. Brouwer (2015), “Agri-environmental policy valuation: Farmers’ contract design preferences for afforestation schemes”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 42, pp. 568-577, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.09.017.
[209] Lizin, S., S. Van Passel and E. Schreurs (2015), “Farmers’ perceived cost of land use restrictions: A simulated purchasing decision using discrete choice experiments”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 46, pp. 115-124, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.LANDUSEPOL.2015.02.006.
[118] Llewellyn, R. (2007), “Information quality and effectiveness for more rapid adoption decisions by farmers”, Field Crops Research, Vol. 104/1, pp. 148-156.
[94] Loisel, P. and B. Elyakime (2006), “Incentive contract and weather risk”, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 35/2, pp. 99-108.
[151] Lütz, M. and O. Bastian (2002), “Implementation of landscape planning and nature conservation in the agricultural landscape—a case study from Saxony”, Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment, Vol. 92, pp. 159-170.
[210] Ma, S. et al. (2012), “Farmers’ Willingness to Participate in Payment-for-Environmental-Services Programmes”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 63/3, pp. 604-626, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-9552.2012.00358.x.
[110] Mathijs, E. (2003), “Social capital and farmers’ willingness to adopt countryside stewardship schemes”, Outlook on Agriculture, Vol. 32/1, pp. 13-16.
[83] Matzdorf, B. (2004), “Ergebnisorientierte Honorierung ökologischer Leistungen der Landwirtschaft, Vorteile, Voraussetzungen und Grenzen des Instrumentes.”, Umweltwissenschaften und Schadstoff-Forschung–Zeitschrift für Umweltchemie und Ökotoxikologie, Ecomed, Vol. 16/2, pp. 125-133.
[24] Matzdorf, B., T. Kaiser and M. Rohner (2008), “Developing biodiversity indicator to design efficient agri-environmental schemes for extensively used grassland”, Ecological Indicators, Vol. 8/3, pp. 256-269, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolind.2007.02.002.
[95] Matzdorf, B. and J. Lorenz (2010), “How cost-effective are result-oriented agri-environmental measures?-An empirical analysis in Germany”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 27/2, pp. 535-544, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2009.07.011.
[154] Mccracken, M. et al. (2015), “Social and ecological drivers of success in agri-environment schemes: The roles of farmers and environmental context”, Journal of Applied Ecology, Vol. 52/3, pp. 696-705, https://doi.org/10.1111/1365-2664.12412.
[57] Mettepenningen, E. et al. (2013), “Investigating the influence of the institutional organisation of agri-environmental schemes on scheme adoption”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 33, pp. 20-30, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.12.004.
[16] Meyer, C. et al. (2015), “Design rules for successful governmental payments for ecosystem services: Taking agri-environmental measures in Germany as an example”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 157, pp. 146-159, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2015.03.053.
[113] Michel-Guillou, E. and G. Moser (2006), “Commitment of farmers to environmental protection: from social pressure to environmental conscience”, Journal of Environmental Psychology, Vol. 26/3, pp. 227-235.
[140] Miller, A. et al. (2011), “Factors impacting agricultural landowners’ willingness to enter into conservation easements: a case study”, Society and Natural Resources, Vol. 24/1, pp. 65-74.
[61] Mills, J. et al. (2008), Evaluation of key factors that lead to successful agri-environmental co-operative schemes, Countryside and Community Research Institute.
[51] Mills, J. et al. (2012), Economics of Co-ordination in Environmental Stewardship.
[193] Mokaddem, A. et al. (2016), “Conception d’un paiement pour services environnementaux en pâturages collectifs. Une expérimentation des choix”, Économie rurale 355, pp. 67-89, https://doi.org/10.4000/economierurale.5004.
[33] Moxey, A. and B. White (2014), “Result-oriented agri-environmental schemes in Europe: A comment”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 39, pp. 397-399, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2014.04.008.
[26] Musters, C. et al. (2001), “Breeding Birds as a Farm Product”, Conservation Biology, Vol. 15/2, pp. 363-369.
[128] Naeem, S. et al. (2015), Get the science right when paying for nature’s services: Few projects adequately address design and evaluation, American Association for the Advancement of Science, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aaa1403.
[145] Niens, C. and R. Marggraf (2010), “Recommendations for increasing the acceptance of agri-environmental schemes – results of an empirical study in Lower Saxony”, Berichte über Landwirtschaft, Vol. 88/1, pp. 5-36.
[12] OECD (2019), Digital Opportunities for Better Agricultural Policies, https://doi.org/10.1787/571a0812-en.
[3] OECD (2012), Evaluation of Agri-environmental Policies: Selected Methodological Issues and Case Studies, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264179332-en.
[14] OECD (2012), Farmer Behaviour, Agricultural Management and Climate Change, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264167650-en.
[2] OECD (2010), Environmental Cross-compliance in Agriculture, OECD Publishing, http://www.oecd.org/agriculture/topics/agriculture-and-the-environment/documents/environmental-cross-compliance-in-agriculture.pdf.
[1] OECD (2010), Guidelines for Cost-effective Agri-environmental Policy Measures, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264086845-en.
[49] OECD (2007), Effective Targeting of Agricultural Policies: Best Practices for Policy Design and Implementation, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264038288-en.
[77] Öhlmér, B., K. Olson and B. Brehmer (1998), “Understanding farmers’ decision making processes and improving managerial assistance”, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 18/3, pp. 273-290, https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-5150(97)00052-2.
[36] O’Rourke, E. (2020), Overview of european agri-environment measures with emphasis on a result-based approach, Teagasc and National Parks and Wildlife Service (NPWS).
[182] Ozanne, A., T. Hogan and D. Colman (2001), “Moral hazard, risk aversion and compliance monitoring in agri-environmental policy”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 28.
[165] Ozanne, A. and B. White (2007), “Equivalence of input quotas and input charges under asymmetric information in agri-environmental schemes”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 58/2, pp. 260-268.
[211] Pan, D. et al. (2016), “Farmers’ preferences for livestock pollution control policy in China: a choice experiment method”, Journal of Cleaner Production, Vol. 131, pp. 572-582, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.04.133.
[152] Pasquini, L. et al. (2009), “Devising appropriate policies and instruments in support of private conservation areas: lessons learned from the Klein Karoo, South Africa”, Conservation Biology, Vol. 24/2, pp. 470-478.
[30] Peerlings, J. and N. Polman (2009), “Farm choice between agri-environmental contracts in the European Union”, Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, Vol. 52/5, pp. 593-612, https://doi.org/10.1080/09640560902958131.
[212] Peterson, J. et al. (2007), Choice Experiments to Assess Farmers’ Willingness to Participate in a Water Quality Trading Market.
[214] Peterson, J. et al. (2014), “Transaction Costs in Payment for Environmental Service Contracts”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 97/1, pp. 219-238, https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aau071.
[213] Peterson, J. et al. (2012), The role of contract attributes in purchasing environmental services from landowners, https://agecon.unl.edu/seminars/peterson-abstract.pdf (accessed on 22 March 2019).
[58] Polman, N. (2002), Institutional Economics Analysis of Contractual Arrangements: Managing Wildlife and Landscape on Dutch Farms, Department of Agricultural Economics and Rural Policy, Wageningen University.
[109] Polman, N. and L. Slangen (2008), “Institutional design of agri-environmental contracts in the European Union: The role of trust and social capital”, NJAS - Wageningen Journal of Life Sciences, Vol. 55/4, pp. 413-430, https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-5214(08)80029-2.
[127] Porras, I. et al. (2011), PES and other Economic Beasts: Assessing PES within a Policy Mix in Conservation, http://www.planvivo.org.
[54] Prager, K., M. Reed and A. Scott (2012), “Encouraging collaboration for the provision of ecosystem services at a landscape scale-Rethinking agri-environmental payments”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 29/1, pp. 244-249, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2011.06.012.
[215] Pröbstl-Haider, U. et al. (2016), “Farmers’ Preferences for Future Agricultural Land Use Under the Consideration of Climate Change”, Environmental Management, Vol. 58/3, pp. 446-464, https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-016-0720-4.
[133] Quillérou, E. and R. Fraser (2010), “Adverse selection in the environmental stewardship scheme: does the higher level stewardship scheme design reduce adverse selection?”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 61, pp. 369-380.
[216] Rabotyagov, S. and S. Lin (2013), “Small forest landowner preferences for working forest conservation contract attributes: A case of Washington State, USA”, Journal of Forest Economics, Vol. 19/3, pp. 307-330, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfe.2013.06.002.
[67] Riley, M. et al. (2018), “Will farmers work together for conservation? The potential limits of farmers’ cooperation in agri-environment measures”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 70, pp. 635-646, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2017.10.049.
[217] Rocchi, L., L. Paolotti and F. Fagioli (2017), “Defining agri-environmental schemes in the buffer areas of a natural regional park: An application of choice experiment using the latent class approach”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 66, pp. 141-150, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.LANDUSEPOL.2017.04.033.
[173] Rojas, M. and B. Aylward (2003), What are we learning from experiences with markets for environmental services in Costa Rica? A review and critique of the literature, International Institute for Environment and Development, London.
[218] Rossi, F. et al. (2011), “Assessing landowner preferences for forest management practices to prevent the southern pine beetle: An attribute-based choice experiment approach”, Forest Policy and Economics, Vol. 13/4, pp. 234-241, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2011.01.001.
[146] Russi, D. et al. (2016), “Result-based agri-environment measures: market-based intruments, incentives or rewards? The case of Baden Württemberg”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 54, pp. 69-77.
[81] Ruto, E. and G. Garrod (2009), “Investigating farmers’ preferences for the design of agri-environment schemes: A choice experiment approach”, Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, Vol. 52/5, pp. 631-647, https://doi.org/10.1080/09640560902958172.
[220] Saïd, S. and S. Thoyer (2007), Agri-environmental auctions with synergies, Lameta, Montpellier, http://www.lameta.univ-montp1.fr/Documents/DR2007-07.pdf (accessed on 12 October 2018).
[221] Santos, R. et al. (2015), “Landowner preferences for agri-environmental agreements to conserve the montado ecosystem in Portugal”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 118, pp. 159-167, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.07.028.
[155] Sattler, C. and B. Matzdorf (2013), “PES in a nut shell: From definitions and origins to PES in practice - Approaches, design process and innovative aspects”, Ecosystem Services, Vol. 6, pp. 2-11.
[108] Sattler, C. and U. Nagel (2010), “Factors affecting farmers’ acceptance of conservation measures-A case study from north-eastern Germany”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 27/1, pp. 70-77, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2008.02.002.
[148] Schilizzi, S., G. Breustedt and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2011), Does tendering conservation contracts with performance payments generate additional benefits?, http://www.are.uwa.edu.au.
[149] Schilizzi, S. and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2016), “Incentivizing and Tendering Conservation Contracts: The Trade-off between Participation and Effort Provision”, Land Economics, Vol. 92/2, pp. 273-291, http://le.
[171] Schillizzi, S. and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2007), “Assessing the performance of conservation auctions: an experimental study”, Land Economics, Vol. 83, pp. 225-237.
[78] Schroeder, L. et al. (2013), “Agri-environment schemes: Farmers’ acceptance and perception of potential ’Payment by Results’ in grassland-A case study in England”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 32, pp. 134-144, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2012.10.009.
[222] Schulz, N., G. Breustedt and U. Latacz-Lohmann (2014), “Assessing Farmers’ Willingness to Accept “Greening”: Insights from a Discrete Choice Experiment in Germany”, Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 65/1, pp. 26-48, https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12044.
[22] Schwarz, G. et al. (2008), An analysis of the potential effectiveness of a Payment-by-Results approach to the delivery of environmental public goods and services supplied by Agri-Environment Schemes, http://www.lupg.org.uk.
[75] Sheeder, R. and G. Lynne (2011), “Empathy-conditioned conservation: ‘walking in the shoes of others’ as a conservation farmer”, Land Economics, Vol. 87/3, pp. 433-452, https://doi.org/10.3368/le.87.3.433.
[10] Shortle, J. et al. (2012), “Reforming agricultural nonpoint pollution policy in an increasingly budget-constrained environment”, Environmental Science and Technology, https://doi.org/10.1021/es2020499.
[63] Sommerville, M., J. Jones and E. Milner-Gulland (2009), “A Revised Conceptual Framework for Payments for Environmental Services”, Ecology and Society, Vol. 14/2.
[223] Sorice, M. et al. (2013), “Increasing participation in incentive programs for biodiversity conservation”, Ecological Applications, Vol. 23/5, pp. 1146-1155, https://doi.org/10.1890/12-1878.1.
[224] Star, M., J. Rolfe and E. Barbi (2019), “Do outcome or input risks limit adoption of environmental projects: Rehabilitating gullies in Great Barrier Reef catchments”, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.03.005.
[167] Stoneham, G. et al. (2003), “Auctions for conservation contracts: an empirical examination of Victoria’s Bush Tender trial”, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Vol. 47/4.
[225] Tesfaye, A. and R. Brouwer (2012), “Testing participation constraints in contract design for sustainable soil conservation in Ethiopia”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 73, pp. 168-178, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.10.017.
[98] Toma, L. and E. Mathijs (2007), “Environmental risk perception, environmental concern and propensity to participate in organic farming programmes”, Journal of Environmental Management, Vol. 38/2, pp. 145-157.
[96] Trujillo-Barrera, A., J. Pennings and D. Hofenk (2016), “Understanding producers’ motives for adopting sustainable practices: the role of expected rewards, risk perception and risk tolerance”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 43/3, pp. 359-382, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jbv038.
[17] Uthes, S. and B. Matzdorf (2013), “Studies on agri-environmental measures: A survey of the literature”, Environmental Management, Vol. 51/1, pp. 251-266, https://doi.org/10.1007/s00267-012-9959-6.
[226] Vaissière, A. et al. (2018), “Preferences for biodiversity offset contracts on arable land: a choice experiment study with farmers”, European Review of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 45/4, pp. 553-582, https://doi.org/10.1093/erae/jby006.
[227] Vedel, S., J. Jacobsen and B. Thorsen (2015), “Contracts for afforestation and the role of monitoring for landowners’ willingness to accept”, Forest Policy and Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 29-37, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.FORPOL.2014.11.007.
[25] Verhulst, J., D. Kleijn and F. Berendse (2007), “Direct and indirect effects of the most widely implemented Dutch agri-environment schemes on breeding waders”, Journal of Applied Ecology, Vol. 44/1, pp. 70-80, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1365-2664.2006.01238.x.
[228] Villamayor-Tomas, S., J. Sagebiel and R. Olschewski (2019), “Bringing the neighbors in: A choice experiment on the influence of coordination and social norms on farmers’ willingness to accept agro-environmental schemes across Europe”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 84, pp. 200-215, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.LANDUSEPOL.2019.03.006.
[229] Villanueva, A. et al. (2015), “The design of agri-environmental schemes: Farmers’ preferences in southern Spain”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 46, pp. 142-154, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.LANDUSEPOL.2015.02.009.
[230] Villanueva, A., J. Gómez-Limón and M. Rodríguez-Entrena (2017), “Valoración de la oferta de bienes públicos por parte de los sistemas agrarios: el caso del olivar de montaña en Andalucía”, Economía Agraria y Recursos Naturales, Vol. 17/1, p. 25, https://doi.org/10.7201/earn.2017.01.02.
[178] Vollan, B. (2008), “Socio-ecological explanations for crowding-out effects from economic field experiments in southern Africa”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 67/4, pp. 560-573.
[231] Vorlaufer, T. et al. (2017), “Payments for ecosystem services and agricultural intensification: Evidence from a choice experiment on deforestation in Zambia”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 141, pp. 95-105, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.05.024.
[168] Vukina, T., A. Levy and M. Marra (2006), “Do Farmers Value the Environment? Evidence from the Conservation Reserve Program Auctions”, paper contributed to a meeting of the International Association of Agricultural Economists, Brisbane, Australia.
[232] Wachenheim, C. et al. (2019), “Landowner valuation of a working wetlands program in the Prairie Pothole Region”, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 50/4, pp. 465-478, https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12503.
[233] Ward, P. et al. (2016), “Heterogeneous preferences and the effects of incentives in promoting conservation agriculture in Malawi”, Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment, Vol. 222, pp. 67-79, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agee.2016.02.005.
[90] Wätzold, F. and M. Drechsler (2005), “Spatially uniform versus spatially heterogeneous compensation payments for biodiversity-enhancing land-use measures”, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 31, pp. 73-93.
[150] Wätzold, F. and K. Schwerdtner (2005), “Why being wasteful when preserving a valuable resource? A review article on the cost-effectiveness of European biodiversity policy”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 123, pp. 227-338.
[131] Weinberg, M. and R. Claassen (2006), “Conservation Program Design Rewarding Farm Practices versus Environmental Performance”, United States Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service, http://www.ers.usda.gov/.
[32] White, B. and R. Sadler (2012), “Optimal conservation investment for a biodiversity-rich agricultural landscape”, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Vol. 56/1, pp. 1-21, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8489.2011.00567.x.
[82] Wilson, G. and K. Hart (2001), “Farmer participation in agri-environmental schemes: towards conservation-oriented thinking?”, Sociologia Ruralis, Vol. 41/2, pp. 254-274.
[31] Wittig, B., A. Kemmermann and D. Zacharias (2006), “An indicator species approach for result-orientated subsidies of ecological services in grasslands - A study in Northwestern Germany”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 133/2, pp. 186-197, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2006.06.004.
[164] Wu, J. and B. Babcock (1996), “Contract design for the purchase of environmental goods from agriculture”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 78/4, pp. 935-945.
[89] Wunder, S. (2005), “Payments for environmental services: some nuts and bolts”, Occasional Paper — CIFOR.
[18] Wunder, S., S. Engel and S. Pagiola (2008), “Taking stock: A comparative analysis of payments for environmental services programs in developed and developing countries”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65, pp. 834-852.
[144] Wünscher, T. and S. Engel (2012), “International Payments for Biodiversity Services: Review and Evaluation of Conservation Targeting Approaches”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 152, pp. 222-230.
[41] Wünscher, T., S. Engel and S. Wunder (2008), “Spatial targeting of payments for environmental services: a tool for boosting conservation benefits”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 65/4, pp. 822-833.
[234] Yeboah, F., F. Lupi and M. Kaplowitz (2015), “Agricultural landowners’ willingness to participate in a filter strip program for watershed protection”, Land Use Policy, Vol. 49, pp. 75-85, https://doi.org/10.1016/J.LANDUSEPOL.2015.07.016.
[235] Yu, J. and K. Belcher (2011), “An Economic Analysis of Landowners’ Willingness to Adopt Wetland and Riparian Conservation Management”, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d’agroeconomie, Vol. 59/2, pp. 207-222, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-7976.2011.01219.x.
[91] Zabel, A. and B. Roe (2009), “Optimal design of pro-conservation incentives”, Ecological Economics, Vol. 69/1, pp. 126-134, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.08.001.
[29] Zechmeister, H. et al. (2003), “The influence of land-use practices and economics on plant species richness in meadows”, Biological Conservation, Vol. 114/2, pp. 165-177, https://doi.org/10.1016/S0006-3207(03)00020-X.
Annex 2.A. Economic experiment component: Summary of findings from choice experiment literature review
Annex Table 2.A.1. Choice experiment design features: Selected results from the literature
Source |
Country and region |
Time period |
Choice variables |
Sample size |
No. choice sets |
Survey delivery method |
Payments for |
Estimation method |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Adams et al (2014[72]), Adams et al (2012[186]) |
AUS |
May to September 2009 |
Three labelled attributes [Conservation covenant; Conservation management agreement; Sell] - Payment (as a % of stewardship costs): (0%; 50%: 100%: 150% for 2 attributes, Market value for Sell attribute) - Configuration: (From no land set aside to one small patch; From no land set aside to several patches; From no land set aside to one continuous area; From one small patch set aside to several patches; From several patches set aside to one continuous area) |
92 |
80: 8 blocks of 10 choice sets (no opt-out) |
Face-to-face and mail |
Stewardship Program |
Conditional mixed-effects logit |
Alló et al (2015[187]) |
SPA |
summer 2012 |
- Payment (EUR, per ha): (30; 60; 90; 120) - Flexibility (how much of the total area enrolled in the contract can be excluded without penalty each year): (0%; 40%) - Fine in addition to the return of the payment (EUR, per ha): (0; 200) - Cover crop area: (0%; 20%) - Restriction on land use: (No restrictions; April 1–August 1) |
359 |
8: 2 blocks of 4 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES for bird protection |
Ordered logit model |
Bastian et al (2017[138]) |
US |
? |
- Easement length: (Perpetuity; 20-25 years) - Public access: (Y/N) - Inclusion of wildlife habitat: (Y/N) - Restricted managerial control: (Y/N) - Financial benefit (% of the average land market value): Income and estate tax benefit plus (0; 25; 50; 45; 100)% of average market value of land |
Landowner 2101 / Land trust 291 |
24: (Landowners: 12 blocks of 2 choice sets), (Land trusts: 6 blocks of 4 choice sets) |
|
conservation easements |
RPLM |
Beharry-Borg et al (2013[188]) |
GBR |
January and June 2009 |
- Inorganic fertiliser application per acre: (current level; 25% less; 50 % less) - Farmyard manure application per acre: (current level; 25% less; 50 % less) - Blocking of drainage ‘grips’: (All; Block 50% of existing grips; Block 100% of existing grips) - Contract length (years): (3; 5; 10) - Compensation payment (GBP per ha per year): (2; 4; 10; 16; 22; 28) |
97 (6 protest respondents are included) |
18: 3 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
water quality protection |
CLM and LCM |
Bennett et al. (2018[189]) |
CHN |
2012 |
- Contract length (year): (1; 5; 10) - Release option: (Cannot leave the programme; Can leave the programme without a penalty) - Land area enrolled (% of household land area): (20; 50; 100) - Annual pesticide use reduction (% in comparison to 2011): (5; 10; 20; 30) - Annual cash subsidy (CNY, per mu=1/15ha): (10; 50; 80; 120) |
288 |
72: 9 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face (Not mentioned clearly) |
Coastal Wetlands Protection |
CLM |
Breustedt et al. (2013[190]) (in German) |
GER |
Summer 2010 |
3 labelled attributes [Grassland area enrolled (minimum %): (5; 10; 20)] - Fertilization: (Allowed organic and mineral fertilizers; Allowed organic fertilizer; No fertilizer allowed) - First mowing not before ...: (June 1st; June 22nd) - Maximum number of grazing animals (1 animal = 1 cow or 3 sheep, per ha): (2; 3; 4) - Duration of the contract (year): (1; 5; 10) - Annual compensation (EUR/ha): (250; 350; 450) |
68 |
63: 8 blocks of 8 choice sets ( - 1 for a dominant choice) |
face-to-face |
AES for grassland |
CLM |
Broch et al. (2013[38]) and Broch and Vedel (2011) |
DEN |
Jan-Feb 2009 |
- purpose of afforestation (groundwater; recreation; biodiversity) - option of cancelling the contract (within 5 years; within 10 years; binding) - monitoring (visit) by authorities (0%, 1%, 10%, 25%OTSC) - compensation level (one-time compensation per hectare: EUR0; EUR3600-5600 in EUR400 steps) |
842 |
36: 6 blocks of 6 |
Web-survey |
afforestation |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Brouwer et al (2015[191]) |
GER |
May-September 2012 |
- Area size (% of the farmer's total area of cultivated land): (10; 25; 50) - Forest type: (Commercial production forest; Non-commercial natural forest) - Availability of technical advice: (Y/N) - Public recreational access: (Y/N) - Return to farmland end of the contract: (Y/N) - Contract duration (years): (10; 25; 50) - Compensation (EUR/ha/year): (250; 500; 750; 1000; 1500; 2000) |
Netherlands: 273, Germany: 206 |
120: 20 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Afforestation agreement |
RPLM and Latent class (LC) models |
Chen et al. (2009[107]) |
CHN |
May-August 2006 |
- Conservation payment (100 to 300 yuan/mu with an intermediate value of 200) ***after the first quarter of the survey, the high payment level was adjusted to 250 yuan/mu*** - Programme duration (3; 6; 10 years) - Neighbours’ behaviours (25%, 50%, or 75% of households in the same group would reconvert part or all of their enrolled land plots) |
304 |
9: 3 blocks of 3 choice sets |
Face-to-face |
maintaining forest on their (GTGP) land plots (although experiment related to maintaining forest after programme ends) |
PM |
Chèze, David and Martinet (2017[92]) |
FRA |
June 2016 to February 2017 |
- Profit variation: variation in average annual gross margin per hectare (-EUR50; 0; +EUR50; +EUR100) - Harvest risk: variation in no. years with poor harvest out of ten (0; +1 year; +2 years) - Additional commitments compared to SQ: (none; join AES; joining a Charter (flexible commitment); green certification) - Reduction in health / environmental exposure cf SQ: (0%; -20%; -50%; -80%) |
83 |
16, blocked into 2 groups = 8 choice sets per respondent |
Face-to-face and web-survey |
Reduced use of pesticides |
CLMand RPLM |
Christensen et al. (2011[147]) |
DEN |
December 2009-January 2010 |
- management flexibility: buffer zone width (6m; 6-24m) - management flexibility: use of artificial fertiliser and pesticides in buffer zone (fertiliser can be used; no pesticides or artificial fertiliser) - assistance with contract application (free assistance from extension service, common application form) - contract length (1 year; 5 years) - option to be released from a contract before it expires (no; released without costs once per year) - compensation level (per ha per year: EUR134; EUR 228; EUR 336, EUR510) |
444 |
8 |
Web-survey |
pesticide-free buffer zones |
RPLM |
Costedoat et al. (2016[169]) |
MEX |
November through December 2014 |
- Forest parcels: (Individual decision; Negotiated by the community assembly; All forests of the ejido) - Technical intermediary: (External service provider; Community technician; CONAFOR) - Payment (MXN, per ha per year): (250; 500; 1000; 2000) - Use of payment: (100% cash; 50% cash + 50% collective agricultural productive project (tractors); 50% cash + 50% social project (community public good)) |
82 |
18: 3 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
PES for biodiversity-related ecosystem services |
CLM and Latent class (LC) models |
Danne and Musshoff (2017[71]) |
GER |
January to March 2016 |
- Programme Financing: (Dairy company scheme; Governmental scheme; Food industry scheme) - Annual grazing period (days per year): (120; 150; 180) - Daily grazing period (hours per day): ( 6; 8; 16) - Feeding standards: (Staple feed consisting only of green fodder; Concentrated feed reduced by 20%; Amount of maize silage reduced by 30%) - Price Premium (eurocents per kg raw milk): (1; 3; 5) |
293 |
12 |
Web-survey |
Pasture grazing programmes |
RPLM |
Dhingra et al. (2015[192]) |
US |
spring, summer and fall of 2014 |
- Maximum payment (% of NRCS local county rental rates: 80%; 100%; 120%) - Terms of contract payment (fixed at start; re-adjusted every 5 years) - Contract length (10 years; 15 years) - Establishment cost sharing (50%; 100% government cost share) - Land use restrictions (Idle; graze/hay every other year) |
76 |
23 |
Face-to-face |
Participation in US Conservation Reserve Programme (land retirement) |
Exploded logit model with no ties in ranking |
El Mokaddem et al. (2016[193]) (in French) |
Morocco |
? |
- Collective development of land for anti-erosion (ha): (0; 1000; 3000; 5000) - Area with a specific pasture for sheep grazing (in proportion to the collective pasture area): (0; 1/4; 1/3; 1/2) - Planting fruit trees (in total number of trees planted): (10; 20; 50; 100) - Payment (MAD (1EUR=11,047MAD), per household per year): (200; 400; 500; 600) - Technical assistance (7 days/year): (None, Plant Production, Animal Production, Mixed) |
144 |
16: 2 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Common-pool pastures conservation |
CLM |
Espinosa-Goded and Barreiro-Hurlé (2010[194]) (in Spanish) |
SPA |
? |
- Flexibility on the area under AES: (Free; 50% eligible area) - Flexibility over grazing/harvesting (Free; Prohibited between August and September) - Presence of a mandatory and free technical assistance service: (Y/N) - Fixed payment of EUR1,000 per contract regardless of the area (to cover adoption costs of AES): (Y/N) - Premium level (EUR, per year per ha): (60; 80; 100; 120) |
200 |
96: 16 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES for Nitrogen Fixing Crops in rain-fed areas |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Espinosa-Goded, Barreiro-Hurlé and Ruto, (2010[37]) |
SPA |
June–August 2008 |
- a compulsory enrolment of 50% of eligible area (free; 50% of eligible surface) - flexibility over grazing in the land under the AES (Free; limited, taking into account RDP specifications for specific regions) - fixed one-off payment of EUR1000 as part of the contract (yes; no) - availability of a compulsory and free of charge technical training and advisory service (yes; no) - per ha premium level (per year) (EU/ha: 60; 80; 100; 120) |
300 |
96: 16 blocks of six choice sets |
Face-to-face |
introduction of nitrogen fixing crops in dry land areas |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Franzén et al. (2016[195]) |
SWE |
? |
- Annual subsidy (SEK, per ha): (Arable land 3000 (Other land use 1500); Arable land 4000 (Other land use 2250)) - Time frame for subsidy and commitment (year): (Min commitment 5 (Max extension 20); Min commitment 10 ( Max extension 30)) - Practical support: (No practical assistance for projecting and design of wetland; A collaboration forum, and practical assistance with projecting and designing a wetland) - Economic compensation for construction (% of cost within ceiling): (50–90; 100) - Cost ceiling for compensation (SEK): (100,000; 200,000) |
29 |
8: 2 blocks of 4 choice sets |
|
Wetland creation |
generalized linear mixed model |
Greiner (2015[196]) and Greiner et al. (2014[197]) |
AUS |
April–July 2013 |
- Conservation requirement (short spelling; long spelling; total exclusion) - Compensation level (per ha per year: AUD1; 2; 4; 8; 16; 32) - Contract length (5 years; 10 years; 20 years; 40 years) - Flexibility (yes, no) - Monitoring (self-monitoring w 25% random spot checks; external monitoring) |
104 |
24: 4 blocks of 6 choice sets |
Face-to-face and mail |
Conservation of (extensive) cattle grazing lands |
RPLM and Latent class (LC) models |
Hope et al. (2008[198]) |
India |
? |
- Land commitment to organic farming (acres): (25%; 50%; 75%; 100%) - Organic crop price increase (per 100 Rupees): (5; 7; 9; 11; 13; 15) - Cost of certification (Rupees, per acre): (1,000 as a group; 3,000 as a group; 3,000 as an individual) - Compost price (Rupees,per trolley): (600; 900; 1,200; 1,500) - Labour days to compost one trolley: (4; 8; 12; 16) |
640 |
64: 8 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Wetland conservation |
CLM and LCM |
Hoyos et al. (2012[199]), Etxano et al. (2015[200]) |
FRA / SPA (Basque Country) |
? WTP is based on 2008 value |
- Native forest (% of land converted by cork oak woodland): (2 (status quo); 10; 20; 30) - Biodiversity (Number of endangered species of flora and fauna): (25 (status quo); 15; 10; 5) - Recreation (Conservation status of walking pathways): (Low (status quo); Medium; High; Very high) - Exotic tree plantations (% of land area covered by pine forest): (40 (status quo); 30; 25; 15) - Vineyard (% of land covered by vineyards): (40 (status quo); 30; 20; 10) - Cost (EUR, per year): (0 (status quo); 5; 10; 30; 50; 100) |
221 |
120: 20 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Land use |
CLM and RPLM |
Hudson and Lusk (2004[201]) |
US |
? |
- Expected Income USD (135000; 150000; 165000) - Price Risk Shifted (None; Semi-Fixed; Fixed) - Autonomy (None; Some; Same) - Asset Specificity (10%; 30%; 50%) - Provision of Inputs (0%; 50%; 100%) - Length of Contract (1; 3; 5) |
49 |
73: 4 blocks of 16 choice sets and 1 block of 9 |
Face-to-face |
Undefined generic kind of contract |
CLM and RPLM |
Jaeck et al. (2014[202]) |
FRA |
? |
- Weed control technology: (Intensive chemical weeding (3 applications or more); Chemical weeding with 1 or 2 applications; Mechanical weeding; Manual weed removal) - Varietal choice: (Short cycle (140–150 days); Medium cycle (150–160 days); Long cycle (>160 days)) - Crop rotation: (Long rotation (1 year of rice every 5 years); ‘Cereal’ rotation (2 years of rice every 5 years); ‘Intensive cereal’ rotation (2 or 3 consecutive years of rice)) - Yield (tons, per ha): (yield< 2; 2<yield< 5; 5<yield<7; Yield<7) - Risk (Year): (0; 1; 3) - Single payment scheme (EUR, per ha): (0; 400; 700; 1000) |
104 |
22: 2 blocks of 11 choice sets |
face-to-face |
CAP for rice cropping technologies |
RPLM and LCM |
Kaczan et al. (2013[203]) |
Tanzania |
September and November, 2010 |
- Individual payment for maintenance of agroforest (Approximate USD, per acre per year): (0; 21; 50; 176) - Collective payment provided to a dedicated village development fund (Approximate USD, per acre per year): (0; 21; 50; 176) - Upfront fertilizer payment (Approximate USD, per acre, one-time): (0; 140 (binary variable)) - Conditionality low (No inspections—farmers are required to keep a log book documenting farm activities which may be audited): (Y/N) - Conditionality moderate (Inspecting farmers' farms once per year): (Y/N) - Conditionality high (Inspecting farmers' farms twice per year. Also will ensuring trees are indigenous species.): (Y/N) |
220 |
32: 4 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
PES for avoiding deforestation |
CLM and LCM |
Kreye et al. (2017[204]) |
US |
2014 |
- Incentive type (USD, per acre): (Annual payments; Reduction in the estate tax; Annual depredation payment; Safe harbor agreement) - Technical assistance: (Advice about stewardship practices; Advice about securing water resources; Advice about improving game populations; Help identifying other incentive programmes) - Acres enrolled: (25% of eligible acres; 50% of eligible acres; 75% of eligible acres; 100% of eligible acres) - Contract duration (year): (5 years; 10 years; 20 yearsl; 30 years) - Monitoring agency: (US Fish and Wildlife Service; Florida Fish and Wildlife Conservation Commission; US Department of Agriculture; Independent environmental consultant) |
187 |
16: 2 blocks of 8 choice sets |
|
Panther conservation |
RPLM |
Kreye et al. (2018[205]) |
US |
December 2015 and February 2016 |
Management choices - BMP1: Implement 100% of applicable silvicultural BMPs. - BMP2: Implement at least 85% of applicable silvicultural BMPs. - WLD1: Locate concentrated heavy equipment away from active burrows or nests. - WLD2 Heavy equipment use must be minimized around nests during hatching season. - ADD1: Manage stands to have two age classes. - ADD2: Prescribed fire is applied every 3–5 years in stands over 10 years in age. Landowner empowering policy tools - TA1: Technical assistance is provided to help meet programme requirements. - TA2: NO technical assistance. - FA1: 50% cost-share is provided to help meet programme requirements. - FA2: NO cost-share assistance. - EXP1: Participating landowner is exempted from permitting for the incidental take of State Imperilled Species on their forestland. - EXP2: Participating landowner is NOT exempted from permitting for the incidental take of State Imperilled Species on their forestland. |
200 |
12 |
Mail and web-survey |
Wildlife Best Management Practices |
RPLM |
Kuhfuss et al. (2016[206]) and Kuhfuss, Préget and Thoyer (2014) |
FRA |
Summer 2012 |
- reduction of herbicide (-30%; -60%; -100%) - localised use of herbicide (yes, no) - final collective bonus of EUR 150/ha (yes, no) - free administrative and technical assistance (yes, no) - compensation level/ha (EUR 90; 170; 250; 330; 410; 500) Two-step experiment: - choice of contract - choice of acreage |
290 |
18: 3 blocks of 6 choice sets |
Web-survey |
innovative herbicide-reduction contracts |
Kuhfuss et al (2016): CLM and RPLM, FE and 2-stage Heckman model); Kuhfuss, Préget and Thoyer (2014): LCM |
Latacz-Lohmann and Breustedt (2019[157]) |
GER |
? |
- Fertilisation (organic and mineral allowed; organic permitted; no fertilisation allowed) - First mowing not before (1 June; 22 June) - Maximum grazing with (2; 3; 4) animals per ha (1 animal = 1 cattle or 3 sheep) - Contract period (1; 5; 10 years) - Annual compensation EUR per ha (250; 350; 450) |
68 |
63: 8 blocks of 8 choice sets ( - 1 for a dominant choice) |
Face-to-face |
Protection for breeding birds on permanent pasture |
CLM (For enrolled land area, OLS and multinomial Heckman model) |
Layton and Siikamäki (2009[207]) |
FIN |
? |
Two-steps: - choice of contract - choice of acreage - Payment (ERU): (ranged between about 85 and 11,770) - Contract length: (ranged between 10 and 50 years, in 5-year increments) |
1129 |
3 choice sets |
|
habitat preservation on private lands |
Beta-binomial model and multivariate censored regression |
Leinhoop and Brouwer (2015[208]) |
GER |
May and September 2012 |
- Forest size (%) (5; 10; 25; 50) - Forest type (commercial; non-commercial) - Technical advice (yes, no) - Recreational access (yes, no) - Return to agriculture at end of contract (yes, no) - Contract length (10 years, 25 years, 50 years) - Compensation level (EUR per ha per year: 500; 750; 1000; 1500; 2000; 3000) |
208 |
120: 20 blocks of 6 choice sets |
Face-to-face |
Afforestation |
RPLM |
Lizin, van Passel and Schreurs (2015[209]) |
BEL |
December 2012–February 2013 |
- Lot size (ha): (0.5; 1.5; 2.5; 3.5) - Soil productivity: (Low; Rather low; Rather high; High) - Driving time to home (min): (5; 10; 15; 20) - Distance to other land (km): (0; 0.750; 1.500; 2.250) - Land use restrictions: (None; Crop restriction; Fertilizer restriction; Usage restriction) - Price (EUR per ha): (15,000; 25,000; 35,000; 45,000) |
188 |
16: 2 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Land use restrictions |
RPLM and error component logit |
Ma et al. (2012[210]) |
US |
2008 |
Two-steps: - choice of contract - choice of acreage - annual payment for a period of 5 years (USD per acre, A specific range for each of 4 cropping systems): (A: 4-17; B: 10-36; C: 15-55; D: 20-75) - payment provider: (federal government; non-governmental organisation) - sequence of cropping practices (increasing or decreasing in complexity and expected environmental benefits) |
1,688 |
16 |
|
PES in agriculture |
Double hurdle model (comprised of a Probit for willingness to consider and a Tobit for acreage enrolment) |
Pan et al. (2016[211]) |
CHN |
between July and August 2014 |
- Technical support: (No technical support (baseline); Medium technical support; High technical support) - Pollution fees (Yuan, per head per month): (0 (baseline); 2.8; 5; 10) - Technical standards: (Y/N (baseline)) - Biogas subsidies (Yuan, per household): (0 (baseline); 1000; 1500; 2000) - Manure market (Yuan, ton): (0 (baseline); 100; 150) - Manure handling rate: (Increase 0% (baseline); Decrease 5%; Increase 15%) |
754 |
12: 3 blocks of 4 choice sets |
face-to-face |
livestock pollution control policy |
RPLM |
Peterson et al (2007[212]); (2012[213]); (2014[214]) |
US |
August 2006-January 2007 |
- Application time (hours): (4; 16; 24; 40) - Monitoring: (Annual verification; spot check) - Penalty USD/acre enrolled: (50; 100; 250; 500) - Trading revenue USD/acre enrolled: (3; 7; 15; 25) - Type of practice required: (Filter strip; No-till) - Haying/grazing allowed on filter strip (Yes/No) - Rotational no-till allowed (Yes/No) |
135 |
32: 2 blocks of 16 |
Face-to-face |
Water quality trading |
RPLM |
Pröbstl-Haider et al. (2016[215]) |
AUT |
January and September 2012 |
- Type of management: (Cash crop cultivation; Short-rotation cultivation; Grassland cultivation) - Gross margin (EUR, per ha per year): (Cash crop cultivation: 300; 450; 750; 1200; 1650, Short-rotation cultivation: 150; 375; 550; 725, Grassland cultivation: 75; 150; 250) - Environmental premium (EUR, per ha per year): (Cash crop cultivation: None; Greening premium 50; Greening premium 150, Short-rotation cultivation: None; Climate premium 50; Climate premium 100; Climate premium 150, Grassland cultivation: Austrian AES-funding 300; Austrian AES-funding 600; Austrian AES-funding 900; Austrian AES-funding 1200) - Duration (year): (Cash crop cultivation [rotation period]: 1, Short-rotation cultivation [rotation period]: 15; 20; 25, Grassland cultivation [contract period]: 7) - Potential price fluctuations: (Cash crop cultivation: Low; Medium; High; Very high, Short-rotation cultivation: Low; Medium; High, Grassland cultivation: Low) - Likelihood of complete crop failure: (Cash crop cultivation: Every 2 years; Every 3 years, Short-rotation cultivation: Every 10 years; Every 25 years, Grassland cultivation: Every 5 years; Every 10 years; Every 15 years) |
148 |
48 |
face-to-face |
Land use under climate change (cash crop cultivation, short-rotation forestry, grassland cultivation) |
CLM |
Rabotyagov and Lin (2013[216]) |
US |
February 2009. |
- Payment (USD, per acre per year): (25; 50; 100; 200) - Contract length (years): (10; 30; 50; In perpetuity) - Extent of participation (share of forest stand): (More than 0, but less than 1/3; More than 1/3, but less than 2/3; More than 2/3, but less than entire stand; Entire stand) - “Biodiversity pathway” management: (Y/N) |
678 |
32: 4 blocks of 8 choice sets |
|
working forest conservation contracts (WFCC) |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Rocchi et al. (2017[217]) |
ITA |
? |
- Nature: (No surface; 1/3 surface; 1/2 surface) - Biodiversity: (Do not make it; Creation of hedges) - Landscape: (Do not make it; Creation of fences) - Seeds: (No surface; 1/2 surface; All the surface) - Lisciviation: (No surface; 1/2 surface; All the surface) - Money (EUR/ha per year): (50; 100; 150; 200) |
244 |
16: 4 blocks of 4 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES in buffer areas |
LCM |
Rossi et al. (2011[218]) |
US |
? |
- Replant with SPB resistant Pine: (Required; Not required) - Pre-commercial Thinning: (Required; Not required) - Commercial Thinning: (Required; Not required) - Prescribed Burning: Required (1 time; 2 times;3 times; Not required) - Local Landowner Participation Rate: (5%; 50%) - Incentive Payment (USD per acre): (30; 80; 120; 160; 200; 250) |
173 |
48: 4 blocks of 6 choice sets (24 profiles as the basic foundation, shifting to an additional 24 profiles) |
|
forest management practices (Southern Pine Beetle Risk Reduction Cost-Share Program) |
Heteroskedastic Extreme Value (HEV) models |
Ruto and Garrod (2009[81]), Arnaud et al. (2007[219]) |
Various a |
May-December 2005 |
- Contract length (5, 10, and 20 years) - flexibility in terms of what areas of the farm are entered into the scheme (yes, no) - flexibility in undertaking some of the measures required under the scheme (yes, no) - average time spent on paperwork/administration (less than 2 h/week, 2–5 h/week, or more than 5 h/week). - compensation level (per ha: 5%; 10%; 20%) |
2262 |
24: 6 blocks of 4 choice sets |
Face-to-face |
EU CAP AES (various) |
RPLM and Latent class (LC) models |
Saïd and Thoyer (2007[220]) |
FRA |
August 2006. |
- Level of financial needs - Level of compliance costs with AES - Level of environmental benefits - Level of compensation payment |
32 |
9: 3 blocks of 3 choice sets |
Face-to-face |
Contracting for the grass premium |
BLM |
Santos et al. (2015[221]) |
POR |
October and December 2013 |
- Area size (% of eligible farm land area): (25; 50; 75) - Cattle density (Livestock units per ha of forage area): (0.2; 0.5; 0.7) - Tree density (Number of trees per ha): (20; 30; 40) - Contract duration (Years): (5; 10; 20) - Compensation (EUR/ha/year): (100; 250; 450) |
111 |
64: 8 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES for agro-forestry ecosystem |
RPLM |
Schulz et al. (2014[222]) |
GER |
Summer of 2012 |
- Ecological Focus Area (EFA): (5%; 7%; 10% of a farm’s arable land) - Arable crop diversity: At least 3 crops (in excess of EFA), each covering no less than (5%; 15%; 25%) of arable land - Land creditable against EFA: (None; Land enrolled in AES; Landscape features (hedges, ponds, stone walls, etc.); Land in AES and landscape features) - Permissible use of EFA: (Leguminous crops; Leguminous crops, but they must be grown on twice the EFA; No productive use (EFA must be set aside)) - Choice of EFA location: (Location of EFA can be freely chosen each year; EFA location fixed for 3 years) - Reduction of single payment in case of opt-out (EUR per ha per year): (35; 70; 105; 140; 175) |
128 |
25: 8 choice sets |
Web-survey |
“greening” of the CAP |
BLM and LCM |
Sorice et al. (2013[223]) |
US |
? |
- Conservation easement type: (no easement; permanent donated easement; permanent sold easement) - Contract length (years): (10; 40; 70; 100) - Credit profit margin (USD per credit): (100; 200; 400; 600; 1600) - Payment structure: (25% year 1, 75% year 5; 50% year 1, 50% year 5; 75% year 1, 25% year 5; 100% year 1) - Decision-making: (programme staff make all land management decisions; landowner and staff share decision-making; landowner makes all decisions) - Obligation once conservation agreement ends (if gopher listed as endangered species): (none; baseline; full) - Result (effectiveness, increase in no. gopher tortoises in country as a result of landowners opting in): (0%; 5%; 10%; 15%) |
251 |
48: 8 blocks of 6 choice sets |
|
Maintaining and managing habitat for an at‐risk species, the gopher tortoise (Gopherus polyphemus) |
RPLM |
Star et al. (2019[224]) |
AUS |
February to April 2018 |
- Days of paid work: (0; 5; 10; 25) - Payment (AUD, per day): (0;100; 200; 500;1000) - Extra unpaid days will be required (50:50 risk): (0; 5; 10; 25) - Risk that the project will not fix the problem: (0; 10; 25; 50) |
75 |
32: 8 blocks of 4 choice sets |
face-to-face |
projects to reduce gully erosion and subsequent sediment run-off |
RPLM |
Tesfaye and Brouwer (2012[225]) |
Ethiopia |
July 2009. |
- Principal (contract provider): (Regional Agricultural Bureau; Local Peasant Association) - Contract length (year): (1; 2; 3; 5; 10) - Payment (Birrr (USD 1=12.56 Birr in 2009), per month): (50; 100; 150; 200; 250; 300) - Land use certificate guarantee: (Y/N) - Soil conservation measure: (Stone bund; Soil bund; Fanya juu) - Number of times for additional extension service including monitoring (year): (1; 2; 4; 6) |
750 |
162: 18 blocks of 9 choice sets |
face-to-face |
soil conservation |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Vaissière et al. (2018[226]) |
FRA |
May-June 2016 |
- Management plan: (4 levels of increasingly restrictive (more environmentally friendly) management; opt-out) - Contract length: (9; 18; 25; 40 years; opt-out) - Conditional bonus EUR200/ha/year for additional ecological conditions in management plan (yes; no; opt-out) - Compensation level (base)/ha/year: (EUR800, EUR1100, EUR1500, EUR2000; opt-out) |
144 |
16: 0 block of 8 choice sets |
Web-survey |
biodiversity offsets |
RPLM |
Vedel et al. (2015[227]) |
DEN |
January and February 2009 |
- Purpose of afforestation: (Biodiversity; Ground water protection; Recreation) - Option of cancelling the contract: (Option of cancelling within 10 years; within 5 years; Binding contract) - Monitoring: (1%; 10%; 25%) will be monitored - Compensation (USD, one-time per ha): (3620–5525 in steps of EUR 400) |
853 |
36: 6 blocks of 6 choice sets |
Web-survey |
afforestation |
CLM and Latent class (LC) models |
Villamayor-Tomas et al. (2019[228]) |
GER, SWITZ, SPA |
? |
- Location of trees: (Coordinated; Not Coordinated) - Share of farm: (1%;5%;10%) - Recommendation (endorsement of the programme): (by farmers; by scientists; no particular recommendation) - Payment for action (ERU, per year per ha): (50;100;150;200) |
195 |
12 choice sets |
Mail, Web-survey, face-to-face |
a tree planting measure |
CLM |
Villanueva et al. (2015[229]) |
October 2013 to January 2014 |
- Cover crops area: (25%; 50%) - Cover crops management: (Free; restrictive management) - Ecological focus areas (EFA): (0%; 2%) - Collective participation: (Individual; collective participation) - Monitoring each year: (5%; 20%) - Payment (USD, per year per ha for a 5-year AES contract): (100; 200; 300; 400) |
295 |
192: 24 blocks of 8 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES permanent cropping |
LCM |
|
Villanueva et al. (2017[230])) (in Spanish) |
La Sierra and Los Pedroches (Córdoba), and Sierra Norte (Sevilla), Spain |
October-December 2016 |
- Plant cover surface: (10% (reference level); 30%; 50%; 100%) - Plant cover management: (Free (reference level); Limited; Brushcutter and/or Shredder blade disc; No practice) - Insecticide treatment: ( Free (reference level); Limited; Ecological; No treatment) - Premium for results (EUR/ha): (Non-inclusion of the premium (reference level); Inclusion of a premium for results of EUR 400/ha to be received in the 5th year of the programme) - Annual payment (EUR/ha/year, during the 5 years of AEP): (50; 150; 250; 350) |
254 |
24: 4 blocks of 6 choice sets |
face-to-face |
AES for mountain olive groves |
RPLM - Error Component Specification |
Vorlaufer et al. (2017[231]) |
Zambia |
May and September 2015 |
- Payment vehicle: (Annual cash payment; Monthly cash payments; Voucher payments; Input payments) - Payment levels (ZMW, per year per acre): (60 (8.2USD); 120 (16.4USD); 240 (32.9USD); 480 (65.8USD)) - Contract duration (year); (10; 20) - Implementing organization: (Government of Zambia; NGO) - Forest co-benefits: (No extraction; Firewood extraction; Subsistence extraction; Commercial extraction) |
320 |
16: 4 blocks of 4 choice sets |
face-to-face |
PES for deforestation |
CLM and LCM |
Wachenheim et al. (2019[232]) |
US |
2017 |
- Rental payment (% of local land rental rates reported by NASS): (70; 85; 100; 110%) - Mid-contract adjustment: (payment fixed at the start of the contract; readjusted up or down at mid-contract to reflect changes in local rental rates) - Length of contract (year): (5; 10; 15) - Managed burning: (allowed; not allowed) - Conservation practice: (required; not required) |
672 |
30: 2 blocks of 15 choice sets |
|
working wetlands conservation programme |
Mixed rank ordered logit |
Ward et al. (2016[233]) |
Malawi |
Jun-14 |
- Intercropping required: (Y/N) - Zero tillage required: (Y/N) - Percentage of crop residues mulched: (0; 25; 50; 75; 100) - Programme implementer: (DLRC; NASFAM; TLC; World Vision) - Subsidy level (USD, per acre per year): (0;10; 20;30; 40) |
1791 |
20: 2 blocks of 10 choice sets |
face-to-face |
Conservation Agriculture for soil quality and crop diversification |
RPLM |
Yeboah et al. (2015[234]) |
US |
Summer 2016 |
- Contract length: (10-20 years) - Signing bonus (USD): (0-200) - % of cost share assistance for practice installation: (0-140%) - annual soil rental payment (USD/acre enrolled): (50-275) |
1106 |
108: 36 blocks of 3 choice sets |
Mail and web-survey |
Filter strip programme for watershed protection |
CLM |
Yu and Belcher (2011[235]) |
CAN |
Jul-07 |
- Compensation level: (CAN per acre: 10 - 55 in USD 5 increments) |
212 |
Randomly assigned compensation level varying between CAN10-CAN55/acre |
|
Conserving riparian areas |
Binary PM and CLM |
Notes: a BLM = binomial logit model, CLM = conditional logit model, FEM = fixed effects model, LCM = latent class model, OLS = ordinary least squares, PM = Probit model, RPLM = random parameter logit model. GTGP = Grain-to-Green Program.
Notes
← 1. In the case of results-based schemes there are operational challenges in terms of having the necessary and appropriate agroecological expertise to deliver at farmer, advisor and controls level of paying agencies, since results-based schemes have a higher knowledge need and it will take time to scale up appropriate expertise.
← 2. Note that environmental benefit index (EBI) is used in this document as a general term and it does not refer to the Environmental Benefit Index (EBI) employed to rank and select land parcels to the Conservation Reserve Program (CRP) established by the Food Security Act of 1985 and administered by the US Department of Agriculture (USDA).
← 3. It is important to note that the risk premium will have to be borne by the society in any case. In the case of result-based payments, it is an explicit component of the payment rate paid for by the tax-payer. For practice-based payments, the risk (of not obtaining the desired environmental outcomes) is borne by the society and hence implicitly paid for by the citizen.
← 4. Environmental quality refers here mainly to the inherent environmental quality of the field parcel. It could also include the environmental benefits of a particular environmental pratice adoption of a chosen agri-environmental contract in given field parcel.