The issues discussed in this note are developed at greater length, based around empirical analysis of estimated Phillips curve relationships for all OECD countries, in Turner et al. (2019).
OECD Economic Outlook, Volume 2019 Issue 2
Focus Note 2: Escaping the low-inflation trap
Inflation has remained weak in many OECD countries, particularly in the euro area and Japan, despite the prolonged recovery and despite a broad range of indicators, including the OECD’s own unemployment gap measures, suggesting little labour market slack (Figure 2.3). These outcomes appear to contradict a standard Phillips curve – a long-standing workhorse of macroeconomic analysis – which predicts that as slack is eliminated, inflation should approach "expected" inflation, usually assumed to be anchored at, or close to, the central bank’s inflation target.1 While there are various possible explanations for this puzzle, including that labour market slack is mis-measured, two possibilities explored in this note are: firstly, that a prolonged period of low inflation has resulted in inflation expectations slipping well below central banks’ inflation targets; and secondly, that inflation responses to slack are non-linear. These two possibilities taken together point to the need for renewed policy action in some countries, most notably in Japan and the euro area, in order to escape the low-inflation trap.
The slippage of inflation expectations
Japan provides a salutary example of the danger of allowing inflation expectations to become entrenched at very low levels. A recent sectoral study suggests that Japan is an outlier compared to other countries with a default expectation that prices remain unchanged, so that expected inflation is essentially zero (Watanabe and Watanabe, 2018). This is confirmed in estimated Phillips curves for Japan and, while the introduction of the 2% inflation target in 2013 does appear to have impacted inflation, the effect seems to have been temporary and is difficult to perceive beyond 2015.
Empirical work suggests that a "slippage" variable, which captures persistent past under or over-shooting of the inflation target, helps to explain recent inflation developments across most OECD countries. This slippage term performs better empirically than survey measures of professional forecasts, which are more often used in empirical work to proxy for expectations. The addition of a slippage effect to other potential determinants of inflation also has a clear policy implication because it directly tests for “the risk that a too prolonged period of low inflation becomes embedded in inflation expectations” (Draghi, 2014). The strength of the slippage effect suggests that for most euro area countries, expectations have indeed slipped below target.
The role of the slippage term can be demonstrated by simulating the euro area inflation response to the unemployment gap shock experienced following the Great Recession, with and without the slippage effect (Figure 2.4). In a first simulation, inflation expectations are anchored to the inflation target, which is assumed to be 2% per annum, whereas in a second simulation, expectations are also influenced by persistent deviations of inflation from the target according to an estimated slippage effect. While the initial fall in inflation is quite similar across the two simulations, the long-term effects are strikingly different. In the first simulation, inflation returns quite quickly to the target once the unemployment rate returns to its pre-crisis level. However, in the second simulation, which better approximates what has actually happened, persistent under-shooting of the inflation target leads to slippage in inflation expectations and inflation remains below target, even after unemployment is back to where it started.
Evidence of non-linear effects
The Phillips curve is typically modelled as a linear relationship linking a measure of economic slack to inflation. However, a strand of research has also explored the possibility that the Phillips curve may be non-linear, which could help to explain why inflation has remained weak. The non-linearity may be a function of inflation itself, or a function of economic slack.
Non-linearity depending on inflation
Low sensitivity of inflation to unemployment at low levels of inflation could be due to the presence of downward nominal wage rigidities. If workers resist nominal wage cuts, then excess capacity may have a weaker effect on prices when inflation is already low. It is difficult to carry out convincing tests for this form of non-linearity because most OECD countries have had relatively few years of very low inflation. However, Japan is an important exception because it has a much longer experience of low inflation and tests decisively confirm the presence of downward rigidities when core inflation is below 1% per annum. If this form of downward nominal rigidity were widespread among other countries, it would help to explain why inflation did not fall more following the Great Recession and might also help to explain why inflation has been slow to recover since. The slow recovery of inflation could be a consequence of firms’ inability to cut real wages in the immediate aftermath of the Great Recession having carried over into reluctance to grant wage increases in the recovery phase.
Non-linearity depending on the degree of slack
Another potential form of non-linearity in the Phillips curve may stem from capacity constraints introducing convexity into the effect of economic slack and reducing the sensitivity of inflation to negative output or unemployment gaps (Clark and Laxton, 1995; Macklem, 1997). Spare capacity in depressed conditions may allow firms to satisfy higher demand without abrupt price increases, whereas during strong expansions firms may increase prices more readily as capacity constraints bite and marginal costs increase. Thus, as economic conditions strengthen, inflation may become increasingly sensitive to economic slack, imparting a convex shape to the Phillips curve. According to a survey of dozens of studies published in the last two decades, the slope of Phillips curves is two to three times steeper in boom phases than in contractionary phases (St‑Cyr, 2018). Evidence for a similar form and scale of non-linearity is found in the largest OECD economies when adapting a baseline Phillips curve specification to allow for a non-linear effect from the unemployment gap.
Given that linear Phillips curves imply very weak unemployment gap effects, the policy implications of having two to three times larger effects in boom phases are not necessarily alarming. Such a conclusion is supported by an entirely different type of study by Babb and Detmeister (2017), who find strong statistical support for a non-linear Phillips curve for the United States using metropolitan-wide data, but also calculate that the inflation implications are “only slightly different to the linear version over the next couple of years”.
Summary and possible policy implications
Persistent low inflation outcomes, particularly with unemployment close to pre-crisis levels, raise concerns that the prolonged period of low inflation has become embedded in inflation expectations, particularly in euro area countries and in Japan. Models allowing for the possibility that persistent under-shooting of the inflation target lowers inflation expectations suggest that expectations may be closer to 1% than 2% in many euro area countries. The euro area may be particularly vulnerable to such risks because the commitment to inflation is area-wide and does not apply to any individual country. A lack of close integration of product and, especially, labour markets throughout the euro area means that persistent low national inflation may more easily come to be reflected in national inflation expectations than would be the case if there were an explicit target for national inflation. This slippage of inflation expectations is a cause for concern. With nominal interest rates close to their effective lower bounds, persistently low inflation keeps real interest rates higher than they would otherwise be, which may explain why recoveries have been tepid in some countries. Moreover, if faced with another large negative demand shock, the scope for conventional monetary policy to lower nominal interest rates would be highly constrained.
A linear Phillips curve, incorporating a mechanism by which persistent under-shooting of the inflation target leads to slippage of expectations, if taken literally, would carry the surprising implication that to re-anchor expectations over any medium-term horizon would require a "Great Boom" to mirror the effects of the "Great Recession". However, evidence of non‑linearities in the Phillips curve, whereby positive gaps have a larger inflationary effect than the weak disinflationary effect of negative gaps, would suggest that a more modest period of over-heating might be required, as illustrated by the simulation of a euro area Phillips curve that incorporates such non-linearities (Figure 2.5). Japan is in a similar, but more extreme, situation with inflation expectations more entrenched and even further below the official target and so is likely to require a more prolonged period of over-heating to jump-start inflation expectations, as well as clear communication regarding the permanent commitment to the inflation target as is currently the case.
References
Babb, N. and A. Detmeister (2017), “Nonlinearities in the Phillips Curve for the United States: Evidence Using Metropolitan Data”, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, No. 2017-070, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, Washington, D.C.
Bobeica, E. and A. Sokol (2019), “Drivers of Underlying Inflation in the Euro Area over Time: A Phillips Curve Perspective”, ECB Economic Bulletin, Issue 4/2109.
Clark, P. and D. Laxton (1995), “Capacity Constraints, Inflation and the Transmission Mechanism: Forward-Looking Versus Myopic Policy Rules”, IMF Working Papers, No. WP/95/75.
Draghi, M. (2014), “Monetary Policy in the Euro Area”, Opening keynote speech at the Frankfurt European Banking Congress, Frankfurt am Main, 21 November 2014.
Macklem, T. (1997), “Capacity Constraints, Price Adjustment, and Monetary Policy”, Bank of Canada Review, 1997, 39-56.
St-Cyr, R. (2018). “Non-linéarité de la courbe de Phillips : un survol de la littérature”, Bank of Canada Staff Analytical Note, No. 2018-3 (French).
Turner, D., T. Chalaux, Y. Guillemette and E. Rusticelli (2019), “Insights from OECD Phillips Curve Equations on Recent Inflation Outcomes”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1579, OECD Publishing, Paris.
Watanabe, K. and T. Watanabe (2018), “Why has Japan Failed to Escape from Deflation”, Asian Economic Policy Review, 13, 23-41.