A continued weakening of output growth could be expected to add to uncertainty and raise concern about the effectiveness of the policy tools available to national governments and central banks to respond. Indeed, this concern may already be contributing to uncertainty at present, even with GDP growth stuck at a subdued but stable below-trend pace in many countries. An effective response to a further slowdown in growth requires both timely and well-targeted measures to lift demand in the near term and actions that durably improve the prospects for living standards in the medium-to-longer term. A balanced policy package of this kind will help the potential synergies from complementary actions across different policy areas to be realised.
Illustrative scenarios using the NiGEM global macroeconomic model highlight the benefits that can be obtained from all of the G20 economies collectively undertaking co-ordinated supportive macroeconomic and structural policy actions. The different policy measures considered are:
Each country undertakes additional debt-financed public expenditure of 0.5% of GDP for three years. In the advanced economies, this is assumed to occur via an increase in the volume of government investment. In the emerging-market economies, this occurs via an ex ante rise in nominal government expenditure of 0.5% of nominal GDP (reflecting smaller and less detailed country models). This contributes to slightly smaller multiplier effects in many emerging-market economies, as higher inflation from the initial demand stimulus reduces the real value of the additional nominal government expenditure.
Monetary policy is allowed to become more accommodative in those economies with sufficient policy space.
Policy interest rates are lowered by 100 basis points for three years in all economies apart from Japan and the euro area, where interest rates are held unchanged at their baseline values for three years, and the United Kingdom, where the policy rate is lowered by 50 basis points for three years.
Thereafter, monetary policy is set to operate in a way that takes into account the longer‑term supply‑side gains that arise from enhanced structural reforms discussed below. In effect, this means that forward guidance is being used to help interest rates stay low for longer, inducing private sector investment to strengthen more quickly than it otherwise might have.
Productivity enhancing structural reforms are assumed to occur in all economies.
In the advanced economies, these consist of measures that raise labour-augmenting technical progress (TFP) growth by 0.2 percentage point per annum for five years, with the 1% higher level of TFP being maintained permanently thereafter. In the emerging-market economies, the reforms consist of measures that raise potential output by 1% over a decade, with the increase accumulating gradually over time.
Stronger structural reforms may help emerging-market economies to both expand their own productivity and to catch-up to the productivity frontier. The latter mechanism is not embodied directly in the scenario set out here, potentially underestimating the long-term impact on these economies.
Significant co-ordinated policy actions by all G20 economies at a time when growth is slowing rapidly will also help to improve the confidence of consumers and investors and reduce uncertainty. In the scenario below, this effect is modelled by a 50-basis-point reduction in investment risk premia for two years that fades slowly thereafter. This approach is the mirror image of the shock to uncertainty incorporated in the simulations of US-China trade tensions reported in Chapter 1.