Occupational licensing and non-competition agreements are two important types of labour market regulation in the United States, both covering around one fifth of all workers. While some regulation is needed to protect safety and ensure quality of services, it also creates entry barriers and reduces competition with important costs for job mobility, earnings and productivity growth. Employment opportunities for low-skilled workers and disadvantaged groups tend to be particularly affected by these barriers. The States are mainly responsible for labour market regulation and the variation across States is similar to the variation in the European Union. Harmonising requirements and scaling back occupational licensing as well as restricting the use of non-competition covenants could help to circumvent the secular decline in dynamism. However, attempts to reform often face stiff opposition from associations of professionals. The federal government has limited influence, but can in some cases help by shifting the burden from workers to meet regulatory requirements onto States and employers to show that high and differing regulatory standards are needed.
OECD Economic Surveys: United States 2020
3. Anti-competitive and regulatory barriers in the labour market
Abstract
Labour market fluidity has declined substantially since the late 1990s and coincides with a period of sluggish productivity growth as discussed in Chapter 2. State-level labour market regulation contributes to some of the concerning lack of dynamism, notably occupational licensing and non-competition agreements, which both cover around one fifth of American workers. Labour market regulation plays an important role in protecting workers and consumers and ensuring well-functioning markets. Too much regulation can however result in excessive entry barriers and reduced opportunities for jobs, mobility and entrepreneurship.
The coronavirus pandemic revealed the barriers occupational licensing can create are harmful requiring action to reduce their impact. Many of the health occupations in high demand are regulated in a way that limit the flow of skilled professionals across State borders. States responded to the crisis by waiving many licensing requirements, by allowing out-of-State licensed professionals to obtain temporary emergency licences to practice and by asking retired health workers or students close to graduation to practice on a temporary basis without a licence (NCSL, 2020; FSMB, 2020).
Occupational entry regulations are widespread in many OECD countries and recent evidence suggests detrimental effects for productivity growth (von Rueden et al., 2020). The reason is that entry barriers lower competition pressures to innovate and reduce reallocation of workers from low to high productive firms. Workers with an occupational licence tend to benefit from higher wages, which has some appeal given persistently weak wage growth. However, low-skilled workers, ethnic minorities and workers with weak labour market attachment are much less likely to hold a licensure and benefit from the higher earnings. The rising use of non-competition agreements (between an employer and an employee) likewise tend to deprive these groups the most by reducing their employment options and wages.
The amount and strictness of all types of regulation vary enormously across States judged by a simple word count of administrative codes (Figure 3.1). With almost 23 million words, New York has seven times the amount of regulation as Kansas. Focusing on restrictive words only, California has almost 400,000 regulatory restrictions, nine times the count for South Dakota. Nevertheless, more words of regulation is not necessarily associated with weaker mobility and poorer economic outcomes. Differences in regulation can potentially provide a spur to competition between States and allows for learning through experimentation. On the other hand, persistent differences may suggest that certain States are not adopting best practices.
The extent to which State-level regulation can create barriers is constrained by federal law. In some areas, such as competition policy, the federal authorities have an important role. In addition, as previously regulated industries, such as telecommunications and transportation, were deregulated, restrictions were introduced on States’ ability to introduce new regulation. Where they were not, such as trucking, strong interest groups pushed for State level regulation to protect their markets. In other areas, federal government reach is more limited. For example, environmental regulation is an important area where State-level regulation largely determines costs to businesses and has contributed to large differences in stringency emerging across the country (Keller and Levinson, 2002). In other cases, professional groups have sought to use regulatory policy to erect barriers to entry (Teske and Provost, 2014). This is most apparent with the growth of occupational licensing.
This chapter zooms in on two important types of labour market regulation, occupational licensing and non-competition agreements, both mainly governed by States. It presents new empirical evidence on the links with job mobility and discusses how reforms can increase opportunities for workers and boost dynamism and productivity growth. No-poaching agreements (between two employers) has a similar effect on worker mobility as non-competes and are used in more than half of all major franchisors’ contracts, such as McDonald’s and Burger King (Krueger and Ashenfelter, 2018). The Chapter does not discuss these type of arrangements, among others because no-poaching agreements between independent firms are generally illegal.
Reforming occupational licensing to boost mobility and opportunities for all
Occupational licensing is a form of regulation by which the government establishes qualifications required to practice a profession, usually including specific education, exam and work experience criteria. Only licensed professionals are then legally permitted to carry out the activities reserved by the specific occupation and use the protected title. Typically, this aims at protecting safety and health of consumers and ensuring quality of services. Most countries regulate professions like doctors, dentists and lawyers, but also electricians, engineers and real estate agents are licensed in many countries.
The prevalence of occupational licensing has grown markedly over time in many OECD countries. Today more than 20% of American workers are licensed, up from around 5% in the early 1950s (Figure 3.2). In part, this reflects the growing share of occupations that are typically licensed, including many services not least in healthcare. Calculations suggest that this compositional effect accounts for around one third of the increase from the 1960s to 2008 (White House, 2015). The spread of licensing to new occupations thus explains the majority of the expanding coverage of the workforce.
The coverage of occupational licensing in the United States is very similar to the European Union (EU) and Japan with close to 22% of workers licensed, but lower than in some countries, including Germany with the highest observed share (Figure 3.3, Panel A). Most of the licensing in the United States is imposed at the State or local government level. Unfortunately, the United States does not produce statistics of licensing coverage at the State level. Estimates prepared for this Survey suggest that the variation within the United States is almost as large as across the European Union (Figure 3.3, Panel B), ranging from 15% in some States (Hawaii and Mississippi) to almost 30% in others (Illinois and New Jersey).
Regulating occupations plays a legitimate role in protecting consumers and as a way to ensure markets work effectively. This is particularly important in certain fields where consumers may not be able to observe the quality of the services even after receiving the service (a credence good; Dulleck and Kerchbamer, 2006). For example, in healthcare, patients may be unable to resolve whether an adverse medical outcome is the result of a challenging case, bad luck or poor medical practice; or the reverse in case of a good outcome. Such concerns are pronounced in high-stakes, one-off transactions and when practitioners can inflict serious harm on consumers. Healthcare and legal occupations are typical examples and are among the most licensed occupations in both the United States and the EU (Figure 3.4). However, licensing in healthcare, as well as in education, in the United States is substantially more widespread compared to the EU, whereas transportation and production occupations have a comparably lower share of licensed employment in the United States relative to the EU.
Proponents of occupational licensing point to better quality of services from the professionalization, entry requirements and standards imposed by licensing an occupation. However, evidence of improved quality and higher consumer welfare is mixed. The few available studies of the initial adoption of licensing laws have found positive effects, for instance on maternal and infant mortality when midwives became licensed in the early 20th century (Anderson et al., 2016). Likewise, the quality of physicians improved as a result of licensing restrictions introduced in the late 19th century, according to another study (Law and Kim, 2005). By contrast, studies of more recent changes in licensing coverage and strictness have generally not been able to find significant effects of licensing on the quality of services (White House, 2015; Kleiner, 2017). Presumably, the most valuable licensing rules were implemented first, while the benefits of licensing additional professions today are likely to be much lower or even negative (Kleiner and Soltas, 2019). For some occupations, digitalisation may also be reducing the information advantage of having a government verified licence since consumers now increasingly rely on digital access to online reviews when making choices (Farronato et al., 2020).
The benefits of licensing for some consumers may come at costs to others who face higher prices, reduced employment opportunities and are disadvantaged by weaker aggregate productivity growth. By restricting entry to professions, occupational licensing policies can reduce competitive pressures, allowing incumbents to raise prices and wages. Entry barriers from licensing can be particularly large for foreign firms and foreign workers (e.g. from domestic training and local exam requirements) and thus effectively imposes a non-trade tariff barrier. Reduced job mobility – both within and between States – is not only a concern for productivity, but is also particularly important for groups with low labour market experience, such as young and low-skilled workers, to climb the job ladder (Haltiwanger et al., 2018).
Designing an effective regulatory system that strikes the right balance can present a challenge since efforts to promote quality and consumer welfare through overly stringent licensure requirements can produce unwarranted constraints on competition. Practices differ substantially across States, not only in which occupations are licensed (Figure 3.3, Panel B), but also in the requirements imposed to obtain and renew an occupational licence. A simple assessment of these requirements suggests that there are substantial differences across States in the strictness of occupational licensing regulation (Box 3.1). Regulatory differences can influence economic outcomes, such as employment flows discussed below.
Box 3.1. An indicator for strictness of occupational licensing regulation across States for certain low- and middle-income occupations
Requirements to obtain and renew an occupational licensure can be summarised with a composite indicator for each occupation, ranging from 0 (no licensing) to 6 (licensed with the strictest requirements observed across States). The National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) collected detailed information on occupational licensing regulation for 31 occupations across all States in 2017, covering mostly low- and middle-income occupations such as cosmetologists, plumbers, nurses and real estate agents (NCSL, 2017). Using this information, Table 3.1 proposes a simple composite indicator with four sub-indicators for i) entry restrictions, ii) education and training requirements, iii) renewal requirements and iv) restrictions for ex-offenders. In the first step, all the listed variables are rescaled to the 0-6 interval, with 6 being the most restrictive requirement observed across States for each occupation and 0 being no regulation or a lower bound (e.g. 15 for minimum age). Second, the rescaled variables are aggregated using the weights reported in Table 3.1 for each occupation. To obtain an indicator for each State, a simple average is computed across the 31 available occupations (see Hermansen (2019) for an employment-weighted average).
Table 3.1. Structure of the composite indicator for strictness of occupational licensing regulation
Dimensions and weights applied to each occupation to compute an indicator for the strictness of regulation
Entry restrictions |
Education and training requirements |
Renewal requirements |
Restrictions for ex-offenders |
||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
25% |
25% |
25% |
25% |
||||
No recognition of out-of-State licensures |
25% |
Education level requirement |
25% |
Renewal years |
33% |
Blanket ban on licensure for some offenses |
25% |
Minimum age |
25% |
Number of exams |
25% |
Hours of continued education |
33% |
No limitations on the scope of inquiry on previous convictions |
25% |
“Good moral character” clause |
25% |
Training hours |
25% |
Renewal fee |
33% |
No requirements to only consider convictions related to the occupation |
25% |
Initial fee |
25% |
Experience hours |
25% |
|
|
Board not required to consider rehabilitation when issuing licence |
25% |
Note: The 15 variables applied are rescaled to the interval 0-6, with 0 being no licensing or no restrictions applied and 6 being the highest observed restriction across States (for each occupation). Missing values are replaced with the median across States (for a few occupations a limited number of variables was dropped due to missing information and weights adjusted accordingly).
Source: Occupational Licensing Database from the National Conference of State Legislatures.
Radiologic technologists in Virginia has the most stringent regulation among the observed occupations, scoring 5.1 by the indicator. Massage therapists in Maryland and veterinary technicians in Nevada are next with a 4.4 score. Among licensed occupations, HVAC (heating, ventilation and air conditioning) contractors in Tennessee and barbers in Maryland have the lowest score with 1.1.
The State of Washington has the strictest regulation and Kansas the most lenient regulation according to the simple average across occupations (Figure 3.5). Restrictions for ex-offenders make the largest contribution to the indicator for most States, while entry restrictions and education and training requirements make the smallest contribution on average. The latter partly reflects the substantial variation in training and experience requirements, implying that one State with a very high requirement will put the bar for the most restrictive level (score 6) high. However, in terms of differences across States, entry restrictions display the largest variation, while restrictions for ex-offenders has the lowest variation.
Licensing requirements vary widely across States
A complete picture of occupational licensing requirements across States is only available for a subset of occupations. States define licensed occupations at their discretion and obey no occupational classification scheme, which complicates comparison. Tentative figures suggest that less than 50 occupations are licensed in all States and the District of Columbia (Kleiner and Xu, 2019), while more than 400 occupations are licensed in at least one State. In the absence of major differences in health, safety or quality of outcomes, it is hard to justify such regulatory differences and better data to document State differences could help to facilitate reform towards best practice.
A jobseeker assistance tool sponsored by the Department of Labor, CareerOneStop.org, contains more than 21,000 State licences. It spans from traditional doctor and lawyer licences to specialised titles such as art therapist, beekeeper, bingo operator, boxing timekeeper, concert promoter, fish packer, librarian, rental car agent, seaweed harvester, tv and radio dealer and wrestler. However, not all States provide complete and updated information to the database. The European Commission has similarly launched the Regulated Professions Database, providing information on 600 regulated professions across countries and with contact points to facilitate labour mobility. The federal government should support initiatives to systematically collect and analyse data on licensing regulation and labour market outcomes to help job seekers and inform policymakers on best practices.
A consortium of the National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL), the Council of State Governments and the National Governors Association Center for Best Practices is currently producing research and delivering technical assistance to States (NCSL, 2017; 2019a). The project was able to collect detailed information for 31 occupations, all licensed in at least 30 States, reviewed below. Still, a tremendous effort is required to document the full picture of occupational regulation across States and not least changes in regulation over time.
Entry restrictions to obtain an occupational licensure take many forms (Figure 3.6). Some States set a minimum age of 21 for certain occupations and even as high as 25 to become a private detective in Pennsylvania (Panel A). Often licensing regulation also requires the applicant to maintain a “good moral character” (Panel B), which has usually been interpreted as a ban on individuals with any criminal record (Craddock, 2008; Rhode, 2018). However, this clause provides licensing boards with substantial discretion to decide if the applicant is fit for a licensure. Several States, including Indiana and Kentucky, have recently passed legislation to disallow the use of vague terms like “good moral character”.
Sizeable fees to acquire a licence can also be an important entry barrier. Fees are often the main revenue source for licensing authorities to finance the administrative work, but some States also rely on fees to finance other activities (NCSL, 2019b). The median State charge around USD 250 for a licence across most of the occupations studied here (Panel C), but going as high as USD 3300 for a real estate appraiser licence in Texas or USD 2400 for a dental hygienist licence in Arizona. Other States apply much lower fees and Florida recently implemented a licensing fee waiver for low-income households and military families.
Qualifying for a licensure can require a certain level of educational attainment and passing a number of exams (Figure 3.7). Completing a number of training hours and documenting hours of experience are also required for many occupations (Figure 3.8). These requirements also vary substantially across States. For instance, a real estate appraiser licence requires a bachelor’s degree in 10 States, an associate degree in 38 States and no degree in three States. A home inspector licence requires passing four exams in Alaska, while only one exam is required in 28 States and 19 States do not license.
Cosmetologists and barbers have the longest training requirements across the reviewed occupations with a median of 1500 hours across States (Figure 3.8, Panel A). Yet, Massachusetts, New York and Vermont only require 1000 hours for cosmetologists, while 2100 hours is required in Iowa and 2000 hours in Idaho. The need for training is usually justified as a means to ensure public health, safety and quality. Nonetheless, training requirements are much lower for e.g. emergency medical technicians (median of 160 hours) directly tasked to save lives. Experience requirements and their variation across States can be even larger (Figure 3.8, Panel B). Electricians are only licensed in 31 States, but among those the median experience requirement is four years. Virginia requires ten years of experience to acquire an HVAC contractor licensure, while six States license without any training and experience requirements and 15 States do not license.
Most States require renewal of the majority of occupational licences studied here every two years (Figure 3.9, Panel A). This usually involves continuing education of 10-30 hours on average per year and paying a renewal fee of USD 25-50. Again, some States only require renewal every four years and no ongoing training. For many occupations, upholding frequent renewal may not be necessary to ensure quality and could function as an effective entry barrier.
Occupational licensing reduces job mobility
States with higher coverage of occupational licensing tend to have lower job mobility (Figure 3.10). A simple plot of the share of licensed employment against the total job hire rate, measured as the number of job hires in a quarter relative to employment, shows a negative, albeit weak association (Panel A). Job hires include both hires from non-employment and job-to-job hires (Panel B), which reflect job moves with no or only a short non-employment period. The entry barriers from occupational licensing are likely to affect both types of hiring. Lower hire from non-employment raises concern for reduced employment and labour market participation, while lower job-to-job hire is a key concern for labour reallocation and productivity growth.
The patterns of job-to-job moves between States also appears to be linked with licensing coverage (Figure 3.11). The majority of job-to-job moves takes place between employers in the same State, whereas job-to-job moves across a State border amounts to around 1% of employment per quarter and has been fairly stable since the early-2000s (Panel A). However, a split of States in two groups with low and high licensing coverage indicates that high licensing States tend to attract considerably fewer job-to-job hires from other States compared to low licensing States (Panel B). Job-to-job mobility within high licensing States does not differ much from low licensing States, suggesting that reduced interstate mobility resulting from occupational licensing is the key driving factor.
New empirical analysis produced for this Survey has examined these correlations in detail using a novel and comprehensive Job-to-Job Flows database from the U.S. Census Bureau (Hermansen, 2019; Box 3.2). The results indeed suggest that occupational licensing reduces job mobility. This holds for hires from non-employment to employment and for job-to-job moves. Moreover, differences in occupational licensing regulation across States are found to be particularly detrimental for job-to-job hires that involves crossing a State border.
Using these results in a counterfactual reform simulation suggests that reducing the burden of licensing could boost labour market fluidity (Figure 3.12). The exercise asks what would have happened to the job hire and separation rates if overall licensing coverage had been 5 percentage points lower in 2018 compared to the observed level (21.8% of employment) with a gradual implementation during 2000-2018 (Panel A). This would be a sizeable reform, roughly corresponding to all States lowering licensing coverage to the levels in Idaho and Utah (Figure 3.3). The simulation finds that the 5 percentage points reduction in coverage could increase the job hire rate by 0.1-0.6 percentage point (1-5% increase) (Panel B); increase the job-to-job hire rate by 0.1-0.3 percentage point (1-6% increase) (Panel C); and increase the job separation rate by 0.1-0.6 percentage point (1-6% increase) (Panel D). These are all economically important effects. For instance, the counterfactual increase in the job hire rate corresponds to up to a quarter of the decline observed from 2000 to 2018 (Panel B).
Box 3.2. Empirical analysis of occupational licensing and job mobility in the United States
New empirical analysis of occupational licensing and job mobility has been prepared for this Survey (Hermansen, 2019). In contrast to the majority of existing studies, the analysis includes licensing coverage of almost all occupations and uses administrative data for the near universe of job transitions in the United States. The results are thus close to macro-level estimates of the implications of occupational licensing.
Both larger coverage and higher strictness (defined in Box 3.1) of occupational licensing are found to be associated with lower job mobility (Table 3.2, upper half). This holds for job-to-job hire and separations as well as for transitions in and out of non-employment. For job-to-job moves across States, but within the same industry, larger coverage and higher strictness compared to other States is found to reduce the inflow of job-to-job moves (see Hermansen (2019) for results and methodology).
The sub-indicators of strictness are also analysed in a joint regression to assess their relative importance for job mobility (Table 3.2, bottom half). Higher entry restrictions and renewal requirements are associated with lower job-to-job mobility, while longer education and training requirements is found to be positively associated with job-to-job mobility. This may reflect that such requirements can enhance skills, which can lead to better job opportunities. Lastly, higher licensing restrictions for ex-offenders is found to be associated with lower hiring from non-employment.
Table 3.2. Job mobility is estimated to be negatively associated with occupational licensing
Estimated association between occupational licensing indicators and job mobility measures
Job hire |
Job separation |
|||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Occupational licensing indicator |
Job hire rate |
Job-to-job hire rate |
Non-employment hire rate |
Job separation rate |
Job-to-job separation rate |
Non-employment separation rate |
Coverage of licensing regulation |
– |
– |
– |
– |
– |
– |
Strictness of licensing regulation |
– |
– |
– |
– |
– |
– |
Subcomponents of strictness |
||||||
Entry restrictions |
– |
– |
0 |
– |
– |
0 |
Education and training |
0 |
+ |
0 |
+ |
+ |
0 |
Renewal requirements |
– |
– |
0 |
– |
– |
0 |
Restrictions for ex-offenders |
– |
0 |
– |
– |
– |
0 |
Note: “–” refers to a negative association; “+” refers to a positive association; and “0” refers to no statistical significant association at the 5% level. The reported results are based on cross-sectional estimations across States and industries with sex/age or sex/education as controls.
Source: Hermansen (2019) based on Job-to-Job Flows data, Census Bureau; Occupational Licensing database, NCSL; careeronestop.org; Occupational Employment Statistics, BLS.
Making licensing regulation less strict among the analysed low- and middle-income occupations would also boost job mobility considerably according to the results (Figure 3.13). A back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that if the State of Washington, which has the strictest regulation, deregulated to a median level as in District of Columbia, Georgia and North Dakota, the job hire rate could increase by 0.4 percentage point (3.6% increase) (blue bars). The next four blocks in the figure repeat the simulation for the sub-indicators of licensing strictness. If Nevada, the State with the highest entry restriction score, reduced its score to Virginia’s level, the job hire and job separation rates would increase by around 0.4 percentage point (around 4% increases) (green bars). Reducing education and training requirements from the highest level in Washington to Minnesota’s level, could have reverse effects and reduce the job-to-job hire rate by 0.2 percentage point and the separation rate by 0.3 percentage point (both more than 3% declines) (brown bars). Loosening renewal requirements in Washington to Utah’s level would also have an economically important impact on the job hire and job separation rates (orange bars). Lastly, easing restrictions for ex-offenders in Virginia to California’s level could have a minor, but still economically important effect of 0.1 percentage point on the non-employment hire rate (2.2% increase) (purple bars).
Not only does occupational licensing affect job flows but also earnings. In fact, most of the literature on occupational licensing have focused on wage effects, generally finding a premium of 5-10% (Kleiner and Krueger, 2013; Gittleman et al., 2018; Blair and Chung, 2018), with a notable exception by Redbird (2017). Calculations across workers of different ages suggest that this premium exist at all ages and tends to increase throughout workers’ careers (Figure 3.14). A licensing earnings premium is likely to arise from two effects. First, the entry barrier and requirements on job takers reduce employment in licensed occupations and hence competition, driving up prices of goods and services for consumers. Licensed employees benefit from this through higher earnings, unless the profit flows to e.g. licensing authorities through fees. Second, workers excluded from licensed occupations experience reduced earnings as they may be forced to work in less well-paid occupations or remain unemployed and since supply of workers in unlicensed occupations increases and drives down wages.
A licensing earnings premium need not imply stronger earnings growth over time. In the short term when an occupation becomes licensed, earnings may rise fast as employees benefit from the new entry barrier that can drive up prices and wages. In the longer term, reduced competition and weaker labour mobility will tend to reduce productivity growth (von Rueden et al., 2020), reducing the scope for earnings growth relative to unlicensed occupations and States with more lenient regulation. The background work produced for this Survey also analysed earnings and found some evidence of reduced earnings gain from job-to-job moves towards States with larger coverage or higher strictness of licensing regulation in the same industry (Hermansen, 2019). This could reflect spatial differences in productivity growth because of licensing. Nevertheless, more comprehensive data of licensing and outcomes are needed to draw firmer conclusions on the link between occupational licensing and earnings growth.
Deregulating and harmonising requirements to improve mobility
Occupational licensing reform could boost job mobility and productivity growth by critically reviewing the numerous licences with less than universal coverage. If not all States license an occupation, a stronger empirical case and arguments beyond general concerns for public health and safety should justify licensing in the States that choose to do so. Delicensing or using alternative systems such as voluntary certification (Box 3.3) are then available to regulate in a more growth-friendly manner.
Evaluations of licensures should rely on careful and comprehensive cost-benefit analysis. Notably the degree to which particular licensure requirements are mitigating a quality information or health and safety problem in the marketplace and the degree to which licensure is reducing supply of qualified professionals. Only 12 States have legislation that requires cost-benefit analysis of new licensing proposals (“sunrise” review), while 28 States maintain some sort of “sunset” process to licensing laws in place for some time (Council of Licensure, Enforcement & Regulation). However, the administration of reviews and the dimensions included vary much across States. Colorado has established a unifying and nonpartisan Department of Regulatory Agencies (DORA) responsible for conducting reviews, which many observers view as a best practice approach (e.g. Kleiner, 2015). Moreover, specifying whose benefits and costs should be counted (standing) is a crucial step in licensing cost-benefit analysis. Not only should implications for competition, employment and productivity ideally be quantified, but a strictly State-level perspective may also leave out vital implications at the national level (Dobes, 2019). Using a standardised approach across States could help to address such concerns. In Australia, a Competition Principles Agreement between the federal government, states and territories essentially subjects all legislation to cost-benefit and necessity analyses, including occupational licensing.
Box 3.3. Alternative forms of occupational regulation
There are many approaches to regulate services and balance trade-offs between not restricting competition and ensuring quality and protection of consumer health and safety. Moreover, occupations that do not have their own discrete regulatory regime are not necessarily unregulated, as they can still be regulated by the general law.
Direct regulation of firms and licensed supervisors
For some occupations, monitoring and inspecting firms directly can be more effective and less burdensome to ensure safety and quality for consumers than licensing. Licensing boards assess entry requirements, but may not have the capacity to monitor and discipline licensed practitioners. A related approach is to only require licensing of a supervisor and allow employees without proven qualifications to perform duties, although this has the disadvantage of imposing a certain business structure. In some States, such as Arizona and Georgia, (journeyman) electricians do not need an occupational licence as long as they work for a licensed electrical contractor. In many European countries, licensing of “masters” only are common for plumbers, electricians and similar professions (von Rueden et al., 2020).
Certification
A certified profession is a restriction on the use of title. Anyone can perform the services of the profession, but only those who have been certified are allowed to use the title. This approach is thus less restrictive than licensing, but offers a means to inform consumers on quality of providers. Voluntary certification can be administered by a government agency or a professional association, managing minimum requirements and examinations. Typical examples are car mechanics and travel agents. In practice, certification also brings together active market participants and when widely adopted, the seal of approval can become a de facto entry barrier for meaningful market participation.
Registration
Maintaining registration for a profession simply implies keeping a list of practitioners. This allows consumers to access information on supply and easily reach providers in the event of a complaint. Registration can be combined with minimum standards, such as providing documentation for qualification. However, if quality is hard to observe, registration may not help consumers feel confident in acquiring certain services.
Licensing or not licensing is just one aspect of evaluations. Reviewing and harmonising the large variation in licensing requirements across States is an equally important area for reform, which could produce sizeable efficiency gains and ease job mobility across States. This is likely to require federal initiatives and support to overcome resistance and coordination challenges at the State level, which is discussed below. However, inconsistencies are also present within States. Occupations where quality is not difficult for consumers to observe are frequently more regulated than occupations where quality is hard to observe and where consumers face genuine risks to their welfare.
A licensure obtained in one State is not automatically recognised in other States, effectively imposing internal non-tariff trade barriers. This can be an important obstacle for mobility across States if workers have to repeat the process of applying for a licensure and redo education and training (Johnson and Kleiner, 2017). To facilitate portability of licensures, States have made reciprocity agreements, covering more than half of the State licensures studied here (Figure 3.15). Nonetheless, even among occupations licensed in all States, such as dental hygienists and bus drivers, reciprocity agreements are not in place in all States, suggesting still much scope for reform.
Reciprocity can be made easier through interstate compacts, a formal binding contract between two or more States, or by the use of model laws and model rules to harmonise regulation and facilitate good practice across States (FTC, 2018; CSG, 2019). So far, mainly health professions have adopted interstate compacts (nurses, physicians, physical therapists, emergency medical technicians and psychologists). The Nurse Licensure Compact was the first (implemented in 1999, currently adopted by 34 States) and has been shown to increase job movements of nurses from one compact State to another (Abdul Ghani, 2018). It relies on a mutual recognition/multistate licence model, which allows nurses licensed by one compact State to practice in other member States without giving notice or obtaining another licence. By contrast, the Interstate Medical Licensure Compact (adopted by 31 States) requires physicians to be licensed in each State of practice, but expedites licensure. Most of the other health profession compacts rely on a mutual recognition model similar to that of the Nurse Licensure Compact, but were activated in recent years and have been adopted by fewer States. While effective, interstate compacts are mainly relevant for large occupations licensed in almost all States since they require time and resources to form. States must adopt the proposed legislation and all compact States must agree to any modifications. Model laws are more flexible than compacts, and licence portability provisions in some model laws, such as the Uniform Accountancy Act, have been adopted by all U.S. jurisdictions. It relies on a mutual recognition model that allows accountants to practice across State borders without notice (FTC, 2018).
Conversely, nothing prevents a State from recognising licences obtained in other States, which corresponds to a unilateral removal of a trade barrier. Recently Arizona became the first State to automatically grant occupational licences to anyone who moves there with a licence from another State (House Bill 2596). This extends a widespread practice for military spouses that typically must move multiple times during their careers (NCSL, 2019b). The automatic recognition does not eliminate all reciprocity barriers though, since it only applies to residents and does not allow commuters to work with an out-of-State licence. Moreover, no other States have indicated they would follow the radical and welcoming move of Arizona, which leaves cumbersome State-by-State reciprocity agreements or nationwide initiatives based on model laws or instate compacts as the main tools to ease cross-border job mobility.
Other federal OECD countries have addressed the mobility challenge in different ways (Box 3.4). Canada has implemented an internal free trade agreement to facilitate recognition of licences across provinces, Australia attempted to form a national licensing system, but reversed to rely on mutual recognition agreements, while Germany has a mix of regulation at both the federal and Länder level.
Box 3.4. Regulation of occupations in other federal countries
Canada
In 2014, approximately 11% of Canadian workers could be identified as licensed (Zhang, 2019). Occupational regulation is highly decentralised, mainly at the provincial level. 106 occupations are licensed in at least one province, varying from 47 in Newfoundland and Labrador to 98 in Quebec. Although there is no specific centralised regulatory body, several occupations (e.g. aviation inspectors, pilots and immigration consultants) are regulated at the federal level.
An internal free trade agreement between the federal government and provinces and territories (signed in 1995 and updated in 2009) encourages labour mobility while respecting local governments’ right to regulate. Workers can generally move freely with their existing licence or certification without having to do significant additional training, work experience or examination. In a few cases of very different standards, exceptions are made, but requires a legitimate objective such as protecting public safety or the environment. Four provinces have gone further and established full mutual recognition of all regulated occupations (New West Partnership).
Australia
In 2011, around 18% of workers in Australia worked in an occupation subject to regulation (Productivity Commission, 2015). States and territories regulate occupations, covering as much as 180 occupations in total. In 2008, an attempt was made to establish a national occupational licensing system to allow licensed workers to work throughout Australia. However, in 2013, the majority of states and territories rejected the reform because of concerns with the proposed model and potential costs. Decentralised reforms to enhance flexibility and mobility of workers are being pursued based on a mutual recognition act from 1992. This was further extended to include both Australia and New Zealand through the Trans-Tasman Mutual Recognition Act from 1997. Mobility through mutual recognition allows workers to apply for a licence for the same occupation in a second state or territory, which will be granted if the authority assess the two to be equivalent. However, the approach has drawbacks since it requires each state and territory to put in place their own legislation to support mutual recognition (as for reciprocity agreements). Indeed a recent committee report to the Australian senate characterised the system as complex, duplicative and burdensome (Select Committee on Red Tape, 2018).
Germany
With 33% licensed workers, Germany has the highest licensing coverage across countries with available data (Figure 3.3). There are 150 regulated professions; some are regulated at the federal level (e.g. doctors, nurses and physiotherapists) and others at the Länder level (e.g. architects, engineers and teachers). Sector-specific business chambers in the professional services and crafts are largely self-regulating (OECD, 2016).
A federal reform in 2004 replaced occupational licensing requirements with a certification regime in 53 out of 94 crafts professions. This resulted in an increase in entrepreneurship, measured as higher entry into self-employment and mainly among untrained workers (Rostam-Afschar, 2014). Nevertheless, parts of the reform were recently reversed, relicensing 20 crafts from 2020.
Making substantial progress on mutual licensing recognition across States will likely require intervention by the federal government. States should retain the main responsibility of occupational licensing to ensure alignment with the broader set of State labour market policies. However, federal law could require States to recognise licences obtained in other States by default, allowing States to set stricter standards only if they can prove this is needed to protect public safety. This would allow States to maintain their current regulation standards, but shift the burden from workers to meet licensure standards onto States to justify higher requirements. Such legislation is justified by the apparent cross-border aspect of practising on the market and the growing evidence of licensing restraining competition, raising prices and not improving quality (Kleiner, 2017). Nevertheless, such a proposal would be drastic and require pre-empting State law, which usually requires a clear cross-border aspect to justify federal intervention. At least one attempt has been made along these lines (Scheffler, 2019). The 1993 Clinton health care plan included a provision stating: “No State may, through licensure or otherwise, restrict the practice of any class of health professionals beyond what is justified by the skills and training of such professionals” (Health Security Act, 1994). Alternatively, the federal government could act as a broker between States to reach broader reciprocity agreements for sectors or major occupations. Ultimately, this could lead to an internal free trade agreement covering all occupations as in Canada (Box 3.4).
Addressing licensing restrictions affecting specific populations
Entry barriers from occupational licensing sometimes affect specific population groups, which can give rise to inequalities. Holding a licensure is more frequent among whites than other race and ethnic groups (Figure 3.16, Panel A). In contrast to the EU, licensed workers in the United States are dominated by women and higher educated (Panels B and C). This reflects the larger licensing coverage in female-dominated occupations such as health and education (Figure 3.4). The large majority of licensed workers are private sector employees, while licensed workers in the EU are much more likely to work in the public sector or to be self-employed (Panel D). By and large, this reflects structural differences in the size of the public sector and prevalence of self-employment. Nevertheless, the concentration of licensing among whites with higher education in the private sector may add to income inequality because of the earnings premium associated with licensing.
Improving access to licensed occupations for disadvantaged groups would not only increase their employment and income prospects; reducing protective measures would also strengthen competition from abroad. The share of foreign-born workers is lower in occupations with high licensing coverage (Figure 3.17), supporting the view that licensing work as a non-tariff trade barrier on service provision. States usually require domestic work experience and apply local exam and language requirements for obtaining a licensure. Evidence from the EU finds that the proportion of foreign-born workers is about one-third lower among licensed workers compared to unregulated workers after accounting for differences in worker characteristics (Koumenta and Pagliero, 2017). Noteworthy, this difference disappears for licensed occupations with automatic recognition of qualifications obtained abroad and for certified workers. This suggests that policies to reduce mobility costs in the European Union have been effective in promoting labour mobility (Box 3.5). Extending interstate compacts and reciprocity agreements in the United States to also include qualifications obtained abroad should be a next step for reform.
Box 3.5. Efforts to increase labour mobility for regulated professions in the European Union
As part of the effort to establish a single market for services, the European Commission issued the Professional Qualifications Directive in 2005 (amended in 2013). The Directive sets clearly defined principles and processes for professional qualification recognition across EU Member States with the aim to reduce mobility costs. To have a comprehensive overview the Regulated Professions Database was established, with information on the 600 regulated professions across countries and national contact points. EU countries were also invited to conduct a mutual evaluation of the respective barriers they have in place limiting access to certain professions.
In 2017, a Services Package was launched to further enhance mobility and help Member States to reform regulated professions. In order to introduce new regulations, countries are now mandated to pass a proportionality test to avoid excessive regulation. Moreover, analysis and country-specific reform recommendations were issued for seven groups of professions.
Americans with a criminal record are often the ones facing the hardest barriers from occupational licensing. Background checks can result in automatic disqualification if the applicant has committed serious crime (felony convictions). Yet, less serious offenses (misdemeanours) and arrests that did not lead to a conviction can also result in denial of a licensure (NCSL, 2019c). Some restrictions serve legitimate public safety functions, such as prohibiting people convicted of assaults or abuse from working with children or excluding people convicted of fraud from law and accounting occupations. The key objective is to make sure the conviction is relevant for the occupation sought, so as not to make re-entry more difficult than necessary. However, Texas and Ohio imposes more than 600 specific restrictions related to criminal convictions in the regulation of occupations, much higher than in Vermont and Rhode Island with just around 100 specific restrictions (Figure 3.18).
Such restrictions can exclude a large group of people from many jobs and generate mismatch problems. Estimates suggest that 3% of the adult population has ever been in prison and 8% has a felony conviction (Shannon et al., 2017). Among African-Americans, the corresponding numbers are as high as 15% and 33%. Background checks thus effectively constrain their employment opportunities substantially. This is emphasised by evidence showing that African-American men who do manage to get a licensure enjoy the largest positive wage benefits across race and gender groups, reflecting that a licence can work as a signal of no-criminal history (Blair and Chung, 2018).
States can set standards for licensing boards’ background checks as a way to reduce barriers for individuals with a criminal record. In many States, licensing boards are allowed to ask and consider arrests that never led to a conviction when making their decision. Licensing boards may also deny granting a licence, regardless of whether the conviction is relevant to the occupation sought or how recent it was. A reform in Indiana now requires licensing boards to explicitly list all disqualifying crimes and to exclude any arrest records not resulting in convictions from their consideration (House Bill 1245). Certificates of rehabilitation is another means to improve employment options for ex-offenders, but only used by few occupations and States (NCSL, 2019c).
Ensuring the proper functioning of licensing boards
For most occupations, States have delegated the task to set and enforce licensing restrictions to an occupational licensing board. The vast majority of boards have direct rulemaking authority, while all boards typically serve as an influential advisory unit to other State regulators. This institutional framework can lead to conflicts of interest since 85% of the total 1790 boards in the United States are required by statute to have a majority of licensed professionals, active in the profession the board regulates (Allensworth, 2017). The average State has 36 boards and except for California, active licensure holders dominate more than 70% of boards in all States (Figure 3.19).
Professional board members have expertise in the training, practice and business of their fields and originally they almost exclusively populated the licensing boards. However, as market participants they are also more likely to implement burdensome entry requirements to protect themselves from competition. Evidence is scarce, but among lawyers, one study found that a larger number of persons attempting to acquire a licence was associated with more difficult exams, suggesting that boards respond to increased supply by raising entry barriers (Pagliero, 2013). Reviews have also found that public seats on boards do not always have full voting rights and are often left vacant for considerable time, both of which increase the control of professionals (Allensworth, 2017; McLaughlin et al., 2017). Moreover, it is common that statutes dedicate public seats to consumer members and reserve seats to represent the elderly, groups that are unlikely to possess sufficient expertise to voice competition concerns. Appointing members from State competition authorities, experts in economics or advocates of consumer rights would help to balance the interests of the public on licensing boards.
A 2015 Supreme Court case (Box 3.6) put the spotlight on potential anti-competitive behaviour of licensing boards and forced some States to take action. The ruling clarified that licensing boards are not automatically exempted from federal antitrust scrutiny, although it is still unclear how much the decision in practice will increase boards’ exposure to antitrust actions and constrain regulation. States have several options to comply with the ruling. In California, all non-health licensing boards have had a majority of public members for many years, albeit there is little empirical evidence on the effectiveness of this approach. Alabama, Delaware, Louisiana and Mississippi reacted to the Supreme Court case by establishing committees or commissions tasked with actively supervising the licensing boards controlled by active market participants. Other States assigned the task to existing State agencies such as the Department of Consumer Protection in Connecticut. A third alternative would be to remove specific regulation that violates competition policy and leave boards subject to antitrust scrutiny; a solution that would substantially limit the power of licensing boards to set entry restrictions (Pagliero, 2019).
Box 3.6. The North Carolina Board of Dental Examiners v. Federal Trade Commission case
The 2015 Supreme Court case was about immunity of occupational licensing boards from antitrust law. It originated from non-dentists offering tooth whitening services and sale of teeth whitening kits in North Carolina. The Board of Dentists claimed that the teeth whiteners were practicing dentistry without a licence and threatened them with criminal liability. Members of the Board had a clear interest in restraining competition since State legislation required six of the eight members of the Board to be licensed and practicing dentists. The Federal Trade Commission investigated the case and sued the Board for violating federal antitrust law. The Board claimed to be immune from antitrust laws as it was acting in accordance with State licensing regulations. Nevertheless, the Supreme Court ruled that State licensing boards that are controlled by market participants are not immune from federal antitrust scrutiny, unless they act in accordance with a clearly articulated State policy and are subject to active supervision in the State.
Reviewing licensing board regulation should also consider the organisation of boards and the tasks reserved for each occupation. Some States have almost 50 different boards regulating specific occupations with overlaps in services provisions, especially in healthcare, giving rise to conflicts over scope-of-practice restrictions. For instance, nurse practitioners and dental hygienists are often prevented from offering services that are fully within their competency or require supervision by a physician to do so (Adams and Markowitz, 2018; FTC, 2014; 2019). Such restrictions create barriers to productivity growth and should be balanced against the benefits of licensing health professions. The Ontario province in Canada implemented a radical reform of healthcare providers in 1991 to address problems of scope-of-practice and conflicts of interest (Safriet, 2002; Scheffler, 2019). A profession-specific licensing system controlled by members much like in the United States was transformed to one common regulatory regime for all health professions largely controlled by public appointees. In addition, an advisory council was charged with continually revisiting whether professions should be regulated or not and updating the regulatory framework.
The influence of professionals on licensing boards and on regulation, also through lobbying, may explain the modest reform action observed across States (Table 3.3). The push for licensing reforms has been strong for several years, not least from the federal level. Yet, cases of delicensing have been very rare and typically include licences with very limited use such as citrus fruit packers in Arizona and abstractors in Nebraska. A committee in Michigan reviewed 87 licensed occupations and recommended to delicense 20, but in the end only six occupations were delicensed. An earlier study identified only eight instances of delicensing in 40 years (Thornton and Timmons, 2015). Nevertheless, the limited action masks many failed attempts to reform (Kilmer, 2018; Rege et al., 2019). For instance, the House of Representatives in Florida passed a bill to delicense 24 occupations in 2011, but the Senate refused it as well as a number of subsequent bills. The resistance to delicensing emphasises the need for comprehensive sunrise reviews to avoid excessive licensing in the first place. Professionals tend to view licensing as the last step to raise the status of their profession, which can be a motivation to be licensed beyond the potential monetary benefits.
Table 3.3. Recent occupational licensing reforms at the State level
Selected reforms
State |
Year |
Reform |
---|---|---|
29 States |
2015-19 |
Reduction of barriers to obtain a licensure for people with a criminal conviction. |
17 States |
2014-19 |
Exemption of natural hair braiders from a requirement to obtain a cosmetology, hairstyling or barber licensure. |
13 States |
2015-18 |
State agency established or assigned task to actively supervise licensing boards. |
13 States |
2015-18 |
Easing of licensing restrictions for military personnel and their families. |
7 States |
2014-18 |
Sunset review process implemented, typically with annual review of 20% of licensed occupations. |
Arizona |
2016 |
Delicensing of five occupations (assayers, citrus fruit packers, fruit and vegetable packers, driving instructors and yoga instructors). |
2017 |
Right to Earn a Living Act shifted the burden of proof to the government to justify that licensing is needed. |
|
2019 |
Automatic granting of occupational licensure to new residents with an out-of-State licensure. |
|
Arkansas |
2019 |
Broad licensing reform to reduce entry barriers and red tape (83 bills considered, 45 approved). |
Indiana |
2018 |
Local governments prohibited from imposing licensure requirements on State-licensed professions. |
Florida |
2017 |
Lower-income workers exempted from licensing fees. |
Michigan |
2013-14 |
Delicensing of six occupations (auctioneers, community planners, dieticians and nutritionists, immigration clerical assistants, ocularists and proprietary school solicitors), following a review of 87 occupations and recommendations to delicense 20 occupations. |
Nebraska |
2018 |
Delicencing of abstractors. |
New Mexico |
2018 |
Executive order requiring overhaul of all licences, including new reciprocity agreements and reduced fees. |
Ohio |
2019 |
All licensing boards set to expire every six years unless the legislature explicitly reauthorizes them. |
Tennessee |
2017 |
Delicensing of shampooing hair and licensure to massage animals made temporary. |
Utah |
2017 |
Licensure requirements reduced for electricians, plumbers and contractors. |
Wisconsin |
2017 |
Licensure requirements reduced for barbers, cosmetologists, aestheticians, electrologists and manicurists. |
Source: Kilmer (2018); Rege et al. (2019); Scheffler (2019); Institute for Justice; National Council of State Legislatures.
Successful reforms are often driven by the governor (Kilmer, 2018), as in the case of delicensing in Michigan and out-of-State licensure recognition in Arizona. Making licensing reform a legislative priority and appointing commissions to do the ground work can overcome resistance against reform. Arkansas achieved large-scale licensing reform during 2019 by appointing working groups involving many stakeholders and collecting good data to inform policymakers (Rege et al., 2019). Outside groups such as think tanks and consumer organisations have also helped to inform legislators and the public in some States, paving the way for reform. Some governors have used their power to act unilaterally through executive orders, for instance by mandating reviews of licensing requirements. However, a comprehensive order issued by the New Mexico governor in 2018 to bring regulation below the national average and increase reciprocity has so far had little effect. The federal government and State associations can support occupational licensing reform by sharing the successful experiences.
The federal government has several options to nurture occupational licensing reform, while largely preserving States’ control over the system. However, action at the federal level has been limited in recent years (Table 3.4) and more should be done to drive reform forward. As discussed above, federal intervention would be justified to remove barriers from lack of reciprocity across States. The European Union has achieved some success in this direction through a mixture of pre-emptory regulation, coordination of Member State efforts and judicial intervention (Box 3.5). In the context of competition policy, experience from the European Union also suggests that countries opted for a more independent and forceful regulator at the supranational level than any individual country ever did (Gutiérrez and Philippon, 2019). Correspondingly, the federal government may be less likely to be politically captured by licensure holders and lobbyists than State-level regulators. Under current legislation, the federal government has several available measures to promote licensing reform (Scheffler, 2019):
Reform licensing regulation within federal authority: The federal government has some limited authority over State licences for providers employed at federal agencies, such as military hospitals and the Department of Veterans Affairs. This power has been used to ease licensing restrictions to improve mobility and increase telehealth in recent years (FTC, 2017). While small in impact, it could set standards for States to adopt or pave the way for further federal regulation. Relatedly, States have taken significant action to reduce restrictions for people with a criminal record, which follows initiatives to reduce such restrictions from the federal administration.
Use fiscal support: Congress has provided targeted fiscal support to incentivise States to reform in specific areas. The Licensure Portability Grant Program supported the work on interstate compacts in healthcare, while licensing reciprocity for military spouses have been supported through the National Defense Authorization Act. In recent years, federal funding has been allocated directly to support broad occupational licensing reform in a number of States, although with limited amounts. Such fiscal incentives can help, but are unlikely to have a major impact without becoming costly and more or less prescriptive.
Step up antitrust enforcement: Intensifying the focus of the Federal Trade Commission and the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice on occupational licensing laws is a more promising avenue to remove barriers from licensing. As discussed above, the North Carolina Supreme Court case (Box 3.6) showed that States are not immune to antitrust scrutiny. Both agencies have advocated against excessive licensing regulation for a long time and recently stepped up efforts on scope of practice issues. This should be continued and if needed antitrust law should be clarified and strengthened to ensure unwarranted occupational licensing or unduly stringent licensing does not compromise competition, especially across State borders.
Use other federal programmes to generate additional pressure: The Affordable Healthcare Act increased the demand for healthcare providers and helped to push reforms to expand scope of practice for nurse practitioners. Reforming other federal programmes may similarly help to push States to take action.
Table 3.4. Recent occupational licensing reforms at the federal level
Selected reforms
Year |
Reform |
---|---|
2011; 2016; 2018 |
Expansion of existing licensing reciprocity for military healthcare providers (federal employees), including through telehealth irrespective of location. |
2016 |
Reduction of federal licensing restrictions for people with criminal records (executive order). |
2016 |
USD 7.5M grant to fund research and technical assistance for improving geographic mobility of licensed workers (lead by NCSL). |
2018 |
USD 7M grant to support occupational licensing reform (allocated to 10 States and two associations of State governments). |
2018 |
States allowed to use federal education funds to review licences for unwarranted entry barriers. |
2019 |
USD 2.5M grant to ease licensing barriers for veterans and transitioning service members with military education and training. |
Source: Scheffler (2019); Institute for Justice; National Council of State Legislatures.
Non-competition agreements are often a bad deal for workers
Non-competition covenants (non-competes) in employment contracts is another restrictive measure that hinders labour mobility. By signing such a clause, employees are prohibited from moving to a competitor company or starting up a competing firm after they separate from the employer. The use of these types of clauses has been growing when measured by legal decisions (Figure 3.20). The number of cases has doubled since the early 2000s and the recourse to courts over trade secrets has jumped even further (trade secrets laws can also be used to restrict employee mobility, e.g. Contigiani et al., 2018). There are arguments for non-competes, particularly when on-the-job training is costly and building client relationships are important. In such circumstances, the employee should normally be compensated for agreeing to a non-compete. On the other hand, non-competes may hinder workers finding better quality jobs and deter entrepreneurship, with the risk that these contracts are used in an anticompetitive manner by some firms. Stringent use of restrictive clauses in employment contracts can thus depress both lifetime earnings and potentially productivity growth.
Estimates suggest that 18% of American workers are covered by a non-compete in their current job (Starr et al., 2019a). Usage is more frequent in high-skill occupations such as engineering, ICT and management (Figure 3.21), which are more likely to possess valuable firm-specific knowledge. Yet, 10-15% of workers in office support, transportation and food preparation report being restricted by non-competes, typically occupations with low income and no access to information of value to competitors. Reported cases concerning hairstylists and sandwich makers have added to concerns that firms may use non-competes to effectively limit alternative job options for their workers and suppress wage increases (Dougherty, 2017). Other research suggests the possibility of the increasing use of non-competes among low-income workers may partly be a response to increases in minimum wages (Johnson and Lipsitz, 2019). In jobs with compensation largely based on tips, firms may use a non-compete to claim bargaining power and reduce the risk of quits, which can make it worthwhile to employ a worker at the minimum wage. However, allowing non-competes will still have economic costs since other firms not bound by the minimum wage will also use them.
Enforcement of non-competes differs across States
The regulation of non-competes is a State matter with substantial variation in the United States. Three States – California, North Dakota and Oklahoma – will generally not enforce such agreements (Beck Reed Riden, 2019), although this has not stopped employers including clauses in contracts. In other States, enforcement is based on different versions of the “reasonableness doctrine”, which balances the protection necessary for the firm against the costs to the worker and society. Only 26 States have statutes governing the use of non-competes, the remaining 23 States rely on the common law and navigate based on a complex set of federal and State court decisions (White House, 2016).
Courts can react quite differently when restrictions included in a covenant are judged excessive. In a few States, courts will throw out the entire covenant if it is deemed overbroad along any dimension (“red-pencil” States). Other States allow courts to remove the offending clauses (such as excessive geographical scope) and enforce the remaining conditions (“blue-pencil” States). However, the majority of States permit courts to rewrite the covenant to make it enforceable with the original intent (“reformation” States). The balance between employee and employer interests also vary, with States such as Montana and Virginia enforcing contracts in a worker-friendly matter, while at the other extreme, Florida is more employer friendly and e.g. uses a broad definition of interest that can be protected, including investment in training (Posner, 2019). Differences in enforcement may nevertheless have little impact if workers are unaware and fear costly lawsuits from employers. A large employee-survey across all States found few differences in the use of covenants, including in the States that do not enforce them (Starr et al., 2019a).
Diverse approaches are also apparent internationally. An experimental OECD indicator was constructed in 2012 to quantify the enforceability of non-competes (Galindo-Rueda, 2012), summarising features such as broadness of protected interests, time limit, compensation and modifications permitted. The variation in approaches within the United States roughly matches the variation across OECD countries (Figure 3.22). For example, Mexico has made non-competes unenforceable, as is the case in California. Australia, New Zealand and the United Kingdom enforces non-competes but under rather restrictive circumstances. In most continental European countries, non-competes that are more permissive are enforceable but typically requires payment of compensation to the employee (Meritas, 2017). At the other extreme, non-compete enforceability in Portugal and the Netherlands was as restrictive as in Florida.
The cross-country variation in non-competes enforcement to some extent mirrors the varying approaches to employment protection legislation (EPL, Figure 3.23). Countries such as Italy, Portugal and France scored high both for EPL and for non-competes enforcement, while New Zealand, Canada and the United Kingdom had lower levels in both dimensions. This could be interpreted as a way to preserve symmetry between the rights of employees and of employers. If workers are safeguarded by restrictions on firms to hire and fire (high EPL), they may accept restrictions from a non-compete, which can safeguard firms. This reading disregards the implications for employment and productivity and needs to be supported by rigorous analysis. Nevertheless, it adds to the concern for a growing imbalance in the power relationship between workers and employers, especially in States with high non-competes enforcement and low EPL.
There are sizeable costs and only modest benefits
Market power of employers is receiving more widespread attention and recent studies suggest that in some OECD countries a significant fraction of employment is in highly concentrated labour markets (OECD, 2019a; 2019b). Employers with market power (monopsony) suppress wages and evidence suggest that the link is stronger among lower-income workers, which may also be less likely to benefit from employer-sponsored health insurance. A study based on online job postings found that the average local labour market in the United States is highly concentrated and would trigger concerns for lack of competition according to the merger guidelines for firms (Azar et al., 2018). Defining local labour markets is nevertheless difficult and other studies using broader definitions have found lower, but still sizeable, degrees of concentration, while the few available studies of trends find evidence of decreasing local labour market concentration over time (Rinz, 2018). The high levels of concentration in some places nevertheless warrants reviewing antitrust policies and labour market regulations. Regulation of non-competition clauses is one important aspect, but also includes merger control and colluding arrangements among firms such as no-poaching agreements (OECD, 2019b). On mergers, the United States authorities have confirmed their willingness to systematically scrutinise the effects of mergers on labour markets, but so far no merger has ever been challenged because of labour market concerns (Naidu et al., 2018).
Non-competes can in some cases play an important role in protecting businesses and promoting innovation, in particular when investments in knowledge cannot be protected through patents or other types of contracts. They can also encourage employers to invest in training for their employees. However, the evidence of positive benefits from non-competes is scarce and inconclusive. Recent studies for the United States have found higher enforcement of non-competes to be associated with a higher investment-to-labour ratio in incumbent firms (Jeffers, 2019) and more training (Starr, 2019), but at the cost of lower wages. There is also some evidence of more risky R&D in States with non-competes enforcement (Conti, 2014) and higher firm value and likelihood of firm acquisition (Younge et al., 2014; Younge and Marx, 2016).
By contrast, there is growing evidence that non-competes have sizeable costs in terms of lower mobility, reduced wages and less entrepreneurship, ultimately weighing on productivity growth. For instance, employees with a non-compete on average have 11% longer job tenure after accounting for differences in worker characteristics (Starr et al., 2019b). Workers in technology industries, which are an important source for knowledge spillovers and have a high incidence of non-competes, have lower job mobility and lower wage growth in States with higher enforceability (Balasubramanian et al., 2019). Moreover, constrained workers also tend to redirect their job search to different fields in fear of breaching the non-compete (Starr et al., 2019b; Marx, 2011), which can result in career detours. Entrepreneurship and innovation thus declines because fewer employees leave an employer to create a spinout firm (Starr et al., 2017) or start new knowledge sector firms (Jeffers, 2019). In other research, an increase in venture capital has a bigger impact on stimulating entrepreneurship, patenting activity and employment in States with lower enforcement of non-competes (Samila and Sorenson, 2011).
The evolving evidence supports the view that some firms may be using these clauses in an anticompetitive manner, suppressing workers’ opportunities and wages. One indication is that the non-compete is often presented after the employee has accepted a job offer and few workers report to have negotiated their non-compete, especially after accepting the job offer (Figure 3.24). The late notice is particularly a concern among low-income workers for which a non-compete often is a take-it-or-leave-it proposition (Starr et al., 2019a).
Some States have reformed, but federal action is also needed
In recent years, several States have or are considering to ban the use of non-competes for low-income or low-skilled workers. Oregon was the first State to introduce a minimum earnings threshold in 2008, which resulted in a wage increase by up to 6% among the affected group (Lipsitz and Starr, 2019). Several other measures are available to make non-competes more employee friendly, but only a few States have taken action in recent years (Table 3.5):
Limits on duration and geographical coverage: Some States implemented or clarified the time limit of non-competes, but the vast majority of States have no explicit regulation of duration. Likewise, it is usually also left to courts to decide what constitutes a reasonable geographical coverage.
Prior notice: A few, but growing number of States have adopted policies to protect workers from being asked to sign a non-compete after accepting a job offer. New Hampshire was first to make non-competes provided after a new job is accepted unenforceable.
Compensation: A non-compete can have a “garden leave” clause, meaning that the employee is entitled to compensation during the period of its validity after separating from the employer. This can help to force employers to use non-competes for crucial employees only. Few States have legislation requiring compensation, whereas “garden leave” clauses are common in European countries (White House, 2016; Meritas, 2017). More than 30 States accept continued employment as sufficient compensation to current employees being asked to sign a non-compete. Recently, Washington introduced legislation to require compensation of laid-off workers if the employer wishes to enforce the non-compete (around half of the States enforce non-competes against employees discharged without cause).
Table 3.5. Recent reforms of non-competition covenants in the United States
Selected reforms at the State level
State |
Year |
Reform |
---|---|---|
7 States |
2016-19 |
Non-competes not enforceable for low-income or low-skill workers. |
4 States |
2015-19 |
Restriction on maximum duration of non-compete (between one and two years). |
Hawaii |
2016 |
Non-competes banned for employees of technology businesses. |
Massachusetts |
2018 |
Regulation to make non-competes more employee-friendly (duration, prior notice, compensation, low-incomes). |
New Hampshire |
2014 |
Non-competes required to be provided prior to acceptance of job offer. |
New Mexico |
2016 |
Non-competes generally banned for employees in health care. |
Oregon |
2015 |
Offer letter required to state if signing a non-compete is expected and agreement to be provided at least two weeks before job start. |
Washington |
2019 |
Non-competes not enforceable in case of a layoff, unless employee receives compensation. |
Source: White House (2016); Marx (2018); Posner (2019).
Restricting enforcement of non-competes may however have little effect if employers continue to use unenforceable contracts and workers behave as if they were valid. Non-competes have generally not been enforceable in California since 1872, but still an estimated 19% of workers have signed one in their current job (Starr et al., 2019a). Research have found similar negative effects on mobility in States that do not enforce non-competes, with workers turning down job offers at a higher rate as the main driver across States (Starr et al., 2019b). States like Illinois and New York, have released public guidelines explaining in simple language under which conditions a non-compete is enforceable, which can help to increase workers’ awareness on their rights (OAGI, 2019; NYAG, 2018).
Uncertainty regarding enforcement could also be reduced by not allowing courts to redraft unlawful covenants to make them enforceable, i.e. a more widespread adoption of the “red-pencil” doctrine (OECD, 2019a). The option to delete or rewrite gives employers an incentive to draft unreasonable broad non-competes as there is a low risk of courts rejecting them outright. Even so, employees may still be reluctant to take an employer to court for fear of losing and because of the potential costs. In that case, authorities should take a leading role to ensure an adequate deterrence against abuse of non-competes. Attorney generals of the States of Illinois and New York have recently been very active in investigating unreasonably broad or unlawful covenants, often reaching settlements with significant sanctions for companies. Other States should clarify who has the initiative and right to take legal action on unreasonable use of non-competes. Consideration could also be given to empower enforcement agencies with the right to use administrative sanctions in cases when non-competes contain clauses that are explicitly banned (OECD, 2019a).
Strengthening regulation of non-competes across the United States is likely to require federal action. While several States have pursued reforms in recent years, opposition and lobbying from businesses have also halted many attempts as in the case of occupational licensing. Several bills to regulate non-competes at the federal level have been proposed. Currently, proposals to ban non-competes nationwide or exempt entry and low-income workers are under consideration. Limiting the use of non-competes to particular high-skill workers only would be welcome (OECD, 2019a) and go in the direction taken by a number of OECD countries in recent years (Box 3.7).
Box 3.7. Recent reforms of non-competition agreements in OECD countries
Denmark
The government limited the use of restrictive clauses in 2014 after a Productivity Commission had pointed to frequent and likely costly use of them. An agreement between the social partners formed the basis of the new regulation. With the reform, non-competes can only apply to employees in particularly trusted positions with confidential information, requires compensation and the duration cannot exceed one year. Non-solicitation clauses, which includes no-poaching agreements between employers, also became much restricted.
Norway
Regulation of the use of restrictive clauses was reformed in 2016 from a regime with few limitations to being regulated under the Working Environment Act. Non-competes are only enforceable if the employer has a particular need for protection, they may not exceed one year and requires compensation of the employee. Non-solicitation clauses restricting employees’ customer relations also became subject to similar regulation, while no-poaching agreements generally became prohibited.
Netherlands
A reform to improve the position of flexible workers generally prohibited non-competes in fixed-term contracts from 2015. Regulation for open-ended contracts still allows wide use of non-competes (cf. Figure 3.22).
United Kingdom
The 2015 Small Business, Enterprise and Employment Act made exclusivity clauses for zero hour contracts (no guaranteed hours, no obligation to accept work) unlawful, effectively ruling out non-competes for these type of contracts.
Federal labour law (Fair Labor Standards Act) could be amended to ban non-competes in most situations and stipulate punishment for employers for including banned clauses in employment contracts. However, the widespread use of non-competes in States that do not enforce them suggest that stronger measures may be needed to change practice. In that case, the federal government could outlaw non-competes in general and only allow use in special cases where employers can prove benefits to workers. This would shift the burden of proof from the employee to employers, which is attractive from the perspective of employees, but may come with the risk of triggering numerous court cases.
Regulating non-competes under federal antitrust law could also be considered as a way to achieve strong deterring effect on firms (Posner, 2019). The growing empirical evidence suggests that non-competes causes anticompetitive harm by restricting worker mobility, thus limiting entry to labour markets and reducing wages. The Department of Justice has traditionally taken the lead to fight collusive and anti-competitive practices, including no-poaching and wage-fixing agreements (OECD, 2019b). In principle, non-competes are also covered by federal antitrust law, but the employee’s burden of proof is excessive under current legislation (Posner, 2019). A single employee trying to escape a non-compete would need to demonstrate that the employer possesses market power and that the particular non-compete has reduced competition. This is almost impossible as evidenced by the absence of any successful cases ever. Federal antitrust law could be strengthened to make non-competes presumptively illegal, while still allowing employers to use a non-compete if they can prove the covenant would benefit the worker. Sanctions under antitrust law are much larger than under common law and could thus be effective in disciplining firms in their use of non-competes.
FINDINGS |
RECOMMENDATIONS (key recommendations in bold) |
---|---|
Occupational licensing |
|
Complete and comparable data on occupational licensing regulation across States are not available. |
Set up a centralised database with easily accessible information on licensing requirements across all government levels to inform job seekers and policymakers. |
Cost-benefit analyses of new regulation (“sunrise” reviews) as well as licensing laws in place for some time (“sunset” reviews) are only required in some States. |
Require standardised cost-benefit analysis of any proposed legislation to license an occupation as well as for introducing additional requirements. Establish a process for ongoing reviews of all licensed occupations to harmonise licensing requirements across States. |
Less than 50 occupations are licensed in all States, while more than 400 occupations are licensed in at least one State. Empirical analysis suggest that larger coverage and strictness of licensing regulation is associated with lower job mobility. |
Encourage States to delicense occupations with very limited concerns for public health and safety and act against anticompetitive behaviour. Consider shifting the regulatory approach to (voluntary) certification if incomplete information for consumers remains a concern. |
Licensures obtained in one State are not automatically recognised in other States. Procedures to implement mutual recognition across States can be cumbersome, e.g. interstate compacts. Empirical evidence suggest comparatively larger coverage and stricter requirements are associated with lower job-to-job inflows. |
Use federal law to impose recognition of out-of-State licensures, allowing States to set stricter requirements only if they can prove it is necessary to protect the public. Consider using broader mutual recognition agreements at the sectoral level or for major occupational groups. |
Some population groups are particularly exposed to excessive licensing requirements. Individuals with a criminal record are often excluded from obtaining a licensure. Immigrants with foreign credentials often have to redo training, which also applies to military personnel and their families moving across States often. |
Address excessive employment barriers that create obstacles for ethnic minorities and foreign nationals. Require boards to set specific restrictions on disqualifying criminal offenses. Limit licensing restrictions to occupations directly related to the offense. |
More than 85% of all licensing boards has a majority of active licensure holders with potential conflicts of interest. Public members on boards often have little expertise in competition issues. |
Increase the share of public members with relevant expertise on licensing boards, e.g. from State competition authorities. Make a state agency responsible for active supervision of licensing boards. |
Many attempts to implement broad licensing reforms have failed because of stiff opposition from licensed professions. |
Encourage governors to take leadership in driving reform. Use commissions or task forces to do the groundwork. Involve think tanks, consumer organisations and other outsiders to broaden information among legislators and the public. |
Non-competition agreements |
|
Evidence suggest that non-competes cause anti-competitive harm in the form of lower wages to workers. Current antitrust law is insufficient to scrutinise non-competes because of excessive burdens of proof. |
Outlaw the use of non-competes except where employers can prove benefit to workers. |
Usage of non-competes have become more widespread among low-skilled and low-income workers, who are unlikely to have access to protectable interests of the employer. |
Set a minimum earning or minimum skill threshold for using non-competes to protect low-income workers. |
Enforcement of non-competes varies from not being enforced in three States to strict enforcement in other States, allowing employers to include a broad set of activities, e.g. investment in training. |
Restrict the scope and duration to make no-competes more employee friendly. |
Employees do not always receive compensation for signing a non-compete. Evidence suggest that around a third of all non-competes are presented after the employee has accepted the job offer and that few negotiate the covenant. |
Require firms to give prior notice if a non-compete is expected to be signed. Require compensation to employees for signing a new or revised non-compete. |
In the majority of States, courts are allowed to rewrite unlawful covenants to make them enforceable, giving firms incentive to use overly restrictive covenants. |
Ban State courts from redrafting unreasonable or unlawful covenants in order to make them enforceable. |
Unenforceable covenants are widely used and often workers respect them in fear of retaliations. |
Empower State attorney generals to take legal action on anti-competitive use of non-competes. Provide easily accessible information to employees on their rights. |
References
Abdul Ghani, A. (2019), “The Impact of the Nurse Licensing Compact on Inter-State Job Mobility in the United States”, in: OECD (2019), OECD Economic Survey of the United States: Key Research findings, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://doi.org/10.1787/9789264310278-en.
Adams, E.K. and S. Markowitz (2018), “Improving Efficiency in the Health-Care System: Removing Anticompetitive Barriers for Advanced Practice Registered Nurses and Physician Assistants”, Policy Proposal 2018-08, The Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution.
Allensworth, R.H. (2017), “Foxes at the Henhouse: Occupational Licensing Boards Up Close”, California Law Review, Vol. 105/6, pp. 1567-1610.
Anderson, D.M., R. Brown, K.K. Charles and D.I. Rees (2016), “The Effect of Occupational Licensing on Consumer Welfare: Early Midwifery Laws and Maternal Mortality”, NBER Working Paper, No. 22456.
Azar, J., I. Marinescu, M. Steinbaum and B. Taska (2018), “Concentration in US Labor Markets: Evidence From Online Vacancy Data”, NBER Working Papers, No. 24395.
Balasubramanian, N. et al. (2019), “Locked In? The Enforceability of Covenants Not to Compete and the Careers of High-Tech Workers”, US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies Paper, No. CES-WP-17-09.
Beck Reed Riden LLP (2019), “Employee Noncompetes: A State by State Survey”, Fair Competition Law.
Blair, P. and B. Chung (2018), “Job Market Signaling through Occupational Licensing”, NBER Working Paper Series, No. 24791.
Conti, R. (2014), “Do Non-Competition Agreements Lead Firms to Pursue Risky R&D Projects?”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 35/8, pp. 1230-1248.
Contigiani, A., D. Hsu and I. Barankay (2018), “Trade Secrets and Innovation: Evidence from the “Inevitable Disclosure” Doctrine”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 39/11, pp. 2921-2942.
Council of State Governments (CSG) (2019), Promising Practices on Licensure Mobility, report.
Craddock, L. (2008), ““Good Moral Character” as a Licensing Standard”, Journal of the National Association of Administrative Law Judiciary, Vol. 28/2, pp. 449-469.
Dobes, L. (2019), “Defining Regional “Standing” for Cost-Benefit Analysis in Federal Countries”, Economic Papers, Vol. 38/2, pp. 156-166.
Dougherty, C. (2017), “How Noncompete Clauses Keep Workers Locked In”, New York Times, 13 May, 2017.
Dulleck, U. and R. Kerschbamer (2006), “On Doctors, Mechanics, and Computer Specialists: The Economics of Credence Goods”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 44/1, pp. 5-42.
Farronato, C., A. Fradkin, B. Larsen and E. Brynjolfsson (2020), “Consumer Protection in an Online World: An Analysis of Occupational Licensing”, NBER Working Paper, No. 26601.
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (2019), Comment from FTC staff to North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners regarding proposed rule changes to 21 N.C. Admin. Code 16W.
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (2018), “Policy Perspectives: Options to Enhance Occupational License Portability”, FTC staff policy paper.
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (2017), Comment from FTC staff to the Department of Veterans Affairs regarding its proposed telehealth rule.
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) (2014), “Policy Perspectives: Competition and the Regulation of Advanced Practice Nurses”, FTC staff policy paper.
Federation of State Medical Boards (FSMB) (2020), “U.S. States and Territories Modifying Licensure Requirements for Physicians in Response to COVID-19”, updated 9 June 2020.
Galindo-Rueda, F. (2012), “Knowledge flows and the mobility of skilled employees; an international perspective on the role of non-compete agreements and their legal enforcement”, DSTI/EAS/STP/NESTI/TIP(2012)10.
Gittleman, M, M. Klee and M. Kleiner (2018), “Analyzing the Labor Market Outcomes of Occupational Licensing”, Industrial Relations, Vol. 57/1, pp. 57-100.
Gutiérrez, G. and T. Philippon (2019), “How EU Markets Became More Competitive than US Markets: A Study of Institutional Drift”, NBER Working Paper, No. 24700.
Haltiwanger, J., H. Hyatt and E. McEntarfer (2018), “Who Moves Up the Job Ladder?”, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 36/S1, pp. S301-S336.
Hermansen, M. (2019), “Occupational Licensing and Job Mobility in the United States”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1585, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/4cc19056-en.
Jeffers, J. (2019), “The Impact of Restricting Labor Mobility on Corporate Investment and Entrepreneurship”.
Johnson, J. and M. Kleiner (2017), “Is Occupational Licensing a Barrier to Interstate Migration?”, NBER Working Papers, No. 24107.
Johnson, M. and M. Lipsitz (2019), “Why are Low-Wage Workers Signing Noncompete Agreements?”.
Keller, W. and A. Levinson (2002), “Pollution Abatement Costs and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to US States”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84, pp. 691-703.
Kilmer, M. (2018), “A Look at Occupational Licensing Reform across the United States”, Arkansas Center for Research in Economics.
Kleiner, M. (2017), “The influence of occupational licensing and regulation”, IZA World of Labor, No. 2017:392.
Kleiner, M. (2015), “Reforming Occupational Licensing Policies”, The Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution.
Kleiner, M. and A. Krueger (2013), “Analyzing the Extent and Influence of Occupational Licensing on the Labor Market”, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 31/2, pp. S173-S202.
Kleiner, M. and E. Soltas (2019), “A Welfare Analysis of Occupational Licensing in U.S. States”, NBER Working Papers, No. 26383.
Kleiner, M. and M. Xu (2019), “Occupational Licensing and Labor Market Fluidity”, mimeo.
Koumenta, M. and M. Pagliero (2017), “Measuring Prevalence and Labour Market Impacts of Occupational Regulation in the EU”, European Commission.
Krueger, A.B. and O. Ashenfelter (2018), “Theory and Evidence on Employer Collusion in the Franchise Sector”, NBER Working Paper, No. 24831.
Law, M. and S. Kim (2005), “Specialization and Regulation: The Rise of Professionals and the Emergence of Occupational Licensing Regulation”, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 65/3, pp. 723-756.
Lipsitz, M. and E. Starr (2019), “Low-Wage Workers and the Enforceability of Non-Compete Agreements”, mimeo.
Marx, M. (2018), “Reforming Non-competes to Support Workers”, in: Shambaugh, J. and R. Nunn (eds.), Revitalizing Wage Growth: Policies to Get American Workers a Raise, The Hamilton Project, Brooking Institution.
Marx, M. (2011), “The Firm Strikes Back: Non-Compete Agreements and the Mobility of Technical Professionals”, American Sociological Review, Vol. 76/5, pp. 695-712.
McLaughlin, P.A., M.D. Mitchell and A. Philpot (2017), “The Effects of Occupational Licensure on Competition, Consumers, and the Workforce”, Mercatus Center, George Mason University.
Meritas (2017), Guide to Employee Non-Compete Agreements in Europe, Middle East and Africa.
Morikawa, M. (2018), “Occupational licenses and labor market outcomes in Japan”, Japan & The World Economy, Vol. 48, pp. 45-56.
Naidu, S., E.A. Posner and G. Weyl (2018), “Antitrust Remedies for Labor Market Power”, Harvard Law Review, Vol. 132, pp. 536-601.
National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) (2020), “COVID-19: Occupational Licensing During Public Emergencies”.
National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) (2019a), “The Evolving State of Occupational Licensing: Research, State Policies and Trends”.
National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) (2019b), “Barriers to Work: Improving Access to Licensed Occupations for Veterans and Military Spouses”.
National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) (2019c), “Barriers to Work: Improving Employment in Licensed Occupations for Individuals with Criminal Records”.
National Council of State Legislatures (NCSL) (2017), “The State of Occupational Licensing: Research, State Policies and Trends”.
New York State Attorney General (NYAG) (2018), Non-Compete Agreements In New York State: Frequently Asked Questions.
Nunn, R. (2018), “How Occupational Licensing Matters for Wages and Careers”, The Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution.
OECD (2019a), OECD Employment Outlook 2019: The Future of Work, Chapter 4, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/9ee00155-en.
OECD (2019b), “Competition Concerns in Labour Markets – Background Note”, DAF/COMP(2019)2.
OECD (2016), OECD Economic Surveys: Germany 2016, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/eco_surveys-deu-2016-en.
Office of the Attorney General of the State of Illinois (OAGI) (2019), Non-Compete Agreements: Frequently Asked Questions.
Pagliero, M. (2019), “Occupational Licensing in the EU: Protecting Consumers or Limiting Competition?”, Review of Industrial Organization, Vol. 55/1, pp. 137-153.
Pagliero, M. (2013), “The Impact of Potential Labor Supply on Licensing Exam Difficulty”, Labour Economics, Vol. 25, pp. 141-152.
Posner, E.A. (2019), “The Antitrust Challenge to Covenants Not to Compete in Employment Contracts”.
Productivity Commission (2015), Mutual Recognition Schemes, Research Report, Australian Government.
Redbird, B. (2017), “The New Closed Shop? The Economic and Structural Effects of Occupational Licensure”, American Sociological Review, Vol. 82/3, pp. 600-624.
Rege, G. et al. (2019), NCSL Occupational Licensing Consortium Case Study Reports, American Institutes for Research.
Rhode, D. (2018), “Virtue and the Law: The Good Moral Character Requirement in Occupational Licensing, Bar Regulation, and Immigration Proceedings”, Law & Social Inquiry, Vol. 43/3, pp. 1027-1058.
Rinz, K. (2018), “Labor Market Concentration, Earnings Inequality, and Earnings Mobility”, CARRA Working Paper Series, U.S. Census Bureau, No. 2018-10.
Rostam-Afschar, D. (2014), “Entry Regulation and Entrepreneurship: A Natural Experiment in German Craftsmanship”, Empirical Economics, Vol. 47, pp. 1067-1101.
Safriet, B. (2002), “Closing the Gap Between Can and May in Health-Care Providers’ Scopes of Practice: A Primer for Policymakers”, Yale Journal of Regulation, Vol. 19/2, pp. 301-334.
Samila, S. and O. Sorenson (2011), “Venture Capital, Entrepreneurship, and Economic Growth”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 93/1, pp. 338-349.
Scheffler, G. (2019), “Unlocking Access to Health Care: A Federalist Approach to Reforming Occupational Licensing”, Health Matrix: The Journal of Law-Medicine, Vol. 29/1, pp. 293-355.
Select Committee on Red Tape (2018), Effect of red tape on occupational licensing, Interim report to the Senate.
Shannon, S. et al. (2017), “The Growth, Scope, and Spatial Distribution of People with Felony Records in the United States, 1948-2010”, Demography, Vol. 54/5, pp. 1795-1818.
Starr, E. (2019), “Consider This: Training, Wages, and the Enforceability of Covenants Not to Compete”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 72/4, pp. 783-817.
Starr, E., N. Balasubramanian and M. Sakakibara (2017), “Screening Spinouts? How Non-compete Enforceability Affects the Creation, Growth, and Survival of New Firms”, Management Science, Vol. 64/2, pp. 552-572.
Starr, E., J.J. Prescott and N. Bishara (2019a), “Noncompetes in the U.S. Labor Force”, University of Michigan Law & Econ Research Paper, No. 18-013.
Starr, E., J.J. Prescott and N. Bishara (2019b), “The in terrorem Effects of (Unenforceable) Contracts”, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, forthcoming.
Teske, P. and C. Provost (2014), “State Regulatory Policy”, in: Haider-Markel, D. (ed.), Oxford Handbook of State and Local Government, Oxford University Press.
Thornton, R. and E. Timmons (2015), “The de-licensing of occupations in the United States”, Monthly Labor Review, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
von Rueden, C., G. Nicoletti, I. Bambalaite (2020), “Occupational Entry Regulations and their Effects on Productivity in Services: Measurement and Firm-Level Evidence”, OECD Productivity Working Papers, forthcoming.
White House (2016), Non-Compete Reform: A Policymaker’s Guide to State Policies.
White House (2015), Occupational Licensing: A Framework for Policymakers, report prepared by Department of the Treasury Office of Economic Policy, Council of Economic Advisors and Department of Labor.
Younge, K.A. and M. Marx (2016), “The Value of Employee Retention: Evidence from a Natural Experiment”, Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Vol. 25/3, pp. 652-677.
Younge, K.A., T.W. Tong and L. Fleming (2014), “How Anticipated Employee Mobility Affects Acquisition Likelihood: Evidence from a Natural Experiment”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 36/5, pp. 686-708.
Zhang, T. (2019), “Effects of Occupational Licensing and Unions on Labour Market Earnings in Canada”, British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 57/4, pp. 791-817.