Inflation affects the tax burden of workers, including the household types covered in Taxing Wages. This section explains how, in a progressive tax system, higher nominal wages lead to larger tax burdens and can generate significant increases in nominal tax revenues through the mechanism known as fiscal drag (OECD, 2008[3]). This phenomenon attracted considerable interest in OECD countries due to the rapid inflation in 2022, but it has an impact on workers’ tax burdens even in periods of relatively low inflation; it also affects the distribution of income and the incentives for workers.
Fiscal drag works through several channels, and it can be considered in nominal and real terms (Heinemann, 2001[4]). ‘Nominal’ fiscal drag occurs when the absolute value of thresholds and tax brackets is not adjusted automatically to the full extent of inflation; nominal wage growth will push the incomes of some workers further up the tax schedule. The phenomenon will be especially pronounced in systems where there are more brackets or where large differences in rates exist between brackets (Beer, Griffiths and Klemm, 2023[5]). However, a worker’s tax burden may rise even if they do not move into a higher tax band when a greater proportion of their taxable income is taxed at higher rates.
This mechanism is known as bracket creep, or cold progression. This phenomenon automatically generates higher nominal tax revenues for the government (assuming that employment rates and hours worked remain constant), but it does so in a way that lacks transparency. As (Beer, Griffiths and Klemm, 2023[5]) state, ‘Raising thresholds but by less than the inflation rate (or even freezing them but then cutting tax rates) can appear a politically expedient way to raise real taxes by stealth, while appearing to lower them.’
Inflation reduces the real value of tax-free allowances, flat-rate tax deductions, tax credits and cash benefits, as well as the thresholds for means-tested benefits if these are not adjusted in line with prices. To the extent that these instruments target low-income workers, nominal fiscal drag can have a disproportionately large impact at the lower end of the income distribution, potentially reducing the progressivity of the tax system and exacerbating poverty. Myck and Trzciński note that policy makers might be able to offset adverse distributional consequences of fiscal drag by using the tax revenues it generates to finance redistributive expenditure policies, but this issue is beyond the scope of this chapter (2022[6]).
SSCs are also affected by nominal fiscal drag, although the impacts work in different directions. At the bottom end, fiscal drag will increase revenues by lowering the real minimum earnings threshold for paying SSCs. At the upper end, it will reduce revenues by reducing the value of contribution ceilings. Heinemann finds evidence that higher inflation is associated with an increase in SSCs in OECD countries, suggesting that it is ‘politically easier to increase contribution ceilings and rates in an inflationary environment’ (2001[4]).
‘Real’ fiscal drag, meanwhile, generates higher tax revenues but is not a direct result of inflation as it can occur even when tax systems are indexed perfectly to prices. This form of fiscal drag occurs when wages across the economy grow in real terms. As with nominal fiscal drag, a worker’s tax burden increases with the progressivity of the tax system. This phenomenon can be negated if absolute values in the tax schedule adjust automatically to real wage growth but this rarely happens in practice, as this chapter will show.
Nominal and real fiscal drag have historically been important drivers of increases in tax-to-GDP ratios in the OECD, especially during the 1970s – a period of high inflation that prompted a number of OECD countries to implement indexation policies (Heinemann, 2001[4]). Nominal fiscal drag was also a feature of fiscal consolidation policies adopted in the wake of the Global Financial Crisis (Avram et al., 2013[7]).
High inflation and declining real wages in 2022 led to considerable interest in nominal fiscal drag and the measures that can be taken to mitigate it, especially indexation. Where wages are falling in real terms, a worker could face a larger tax burden on a lower real income, meaning they could be doubly disadvantaged by inflation. Countries in which inflation and tax rates are higher, and in which thresholds have not been updated for longer periods, are most likely to experience the most pronounced effects of fiscal drag.