This chapter focuses on the taxation of self-employed individuals in Lithuania. The chapter begins by considering self-employment trends, the tax rules on self-employment and the characteristics of the self-employed. Next, the tax design and tax burdens of the business certificate and individual-activity regimes are evaluated against each other and standard employment and options for tax reform are presented. Finally, incorporated self-employment under different CIT rates is compared against standard employment and the individual-activity regime.
OECD Tax Policy Reviews: Lithuania 2022
5. The taxation of self-employed individuals
Abstract
Introduction
This chapter provides observations on the tax design and options for tax policy reforms in unincorporated and incorporated business regimes in Lithuania. The unincorporated regimes focus on the business certificate (BC) regime and the individual-activity (IA) regime (the taxation of self-employed farmers is briefly reviewed separately). The regimes are evaluated in terms of their tax design, tax rates and tax burdens, tax-induced incentives between organisational forms (including standard employment), interaction (i.e. migration between them) and adherence to principles of good tax policy (i.e. horizontal equity and tax neutrality). The incorporated business regime section focuses on owner managers of closely-held corporations and the tax-induced incentives between distributing profits as dividends and drawing a salary as an employee under both standard and reduced CIT rate regimes. The chapter is based on analysis using a representative sample of the tax record microdata in 2019. The chapter draws from a forthcoming OECD paper on the design of presumptive tax regimes ( (Mas-Montserrat et al., forthcoming[1])) The self-employment tax rules refer to the year 2021, unless otherwise stated. For simplicity, the following shorthand acronyms are used regularly throughout this chapter:
1. SE refers to self-employed taxpayers.
2. IA refers to individual-activity taxpayers.
3. BC refers to business certificate taxpayers.
Self-employment trends
Self-employment has continued to grow (Figure 5.1, Panel A). Own-account workers represent 17.6% of total employment in 2020, which places Lithuania in the middle range of OECD countries (Figure 5.1, Panel B). While there has been no clear trend across the OECD in the share of own-account workers in total employment between 2010 and 2020, there has been a significant increase in Lithuania.
Self-employment numbers are significant. Individual activity in Lithuania refers to unincorporated self-employment (SE) activity from which income is received regularly. There are two main ways of taxing individual SE activity in Lithuania. They are the individual-activity certificate regime (IA regime) and the business certificate regime (BC regime). The number of individuals in the BC regime represents about half of the IA regime in 2019 (88,208 individuals declared having income under the BC regime and 174 124 declared having income under the IA regime).1 In the IA regime, about one-third of individuals are farmers (116 680 related to non-agricultural income and 57 444 relate to agricultural income). Individuals in the IA and BC regimes combined comprise 18% of employees (there are a total of 1 434 240 individuals with employment income in 20192). Lithuania has a wide range of other categories which do not belong to self-employed or employed categories, which are outside the scope of the current review. Figure 5.3 provides a stylised overview of the organisational forms considered.
Self-employment PIT revenues
PIT revenues from self-employment are low compared to standard employment. The average PIT paid per person is lowest in the BC regime, followed by agricultural activity in the IA regime and then non-agricultural activity in the IA regime (Figure 5.2). The average PIT paid is significantly lower in all of the SE regimes compared to standard employment.
Principles of tax policy design for self-employment
The principle of horizontal equity says that tax and benefit treatment should be aligned across employment forms, but rationales exist for departure from the principle. Equity is the aim that taxation is fair for all taxpayers. Equity can be broken into vertical equity (how individuals with a greater ability to pay should bear proportionately higher tax burdens) and horizontal equity (how similar individuals should face similar tax burdens). This chapter focuses mainly on the latter. The principle of horizontal equity states that tax treatments and benefit entitlements should be broadly aligned across different employment forms (e.g. between employees and the self-employed). However, arguments have been made to justify departures from the principle of horizontal equity in tax treatment beginning with the notion that employment forms face different economic realities in terms of agency over their work, social protections they are afforded and the risk they bear. For example, the job uncertainty, investment loss and competitive pressure of self-employed compared to employment may justify lower tax burdens on the self-employed (Milanez and Bratta, 2019[2]). Similarly, reduced employment rights and different entitlements may justify lower tax burdens.
The principle of tax neutrality says that tax should not be a factor in organisational form decisions, but non-neutral policies can have justifications. Tax treatment is neutral when similar individuals face the same tax burden and tax is not a factor in the organisational form decision. Neutrality implies that decisions are made on economic merit and not for tax reasons. Departures from horizontal equity tax treatment can have implications for neutrality. For example, greater allowable deductions for self-employed workers relative to employed workers (which is commonly the case across countries including in Lithuania) could lead to false self-employment and inflated deductions. Similarly, lower tax rates on capital income relative to labour income (which is commonly the case across countries including in Lithuania) can encourage the self-employed to incorporate their business and re-characterise labour income as capital income (Milanez and Bratta, 2019[2]). Non-neutral policies such as these can however be justified for example on the basis of encouraging economic growth and job creation.
Self-employment tax rules
This section provides an overview of the tax rules for self-employment in the BC and IA regimes compared with standard employment for both PIT and SSCs. The analysis presented for the IA regime includes self-employed farmers and non-farmers. Since the tax rules differ for farmers, farmers are briefly discussed separately at the end of the IA regime section.
PIT rules
Taxpayers in Lithuania can simultaneously belong to several different organisational forms including two self-employment regimes (IA and BC regimes), a standard employment and incorporation (at a standard or reduced CIT rate and then with a choice to pay profits in dividends, in salary or retain in the company). The organisational forms differ in several respects including how income is taxed, deductions, eligibility criteria, record-keeping requirements and the level of government at which taxes are set and collected (Table 5.1). The tax rules described in this section refer to the year 2021. There are other types of self-employment income that exist but which are not considered for the purposes of this report.
Table 5.1. Overview of tax characteristics by organisational form
Regime |
Selected characteristics |
Tax rates & taxable income bands |
---|---|---|
1.Individual-activity certificate (IA regime) |
-Taxable individual certificate income. -Tax credit (maximum of 10%). -Presumed cost deduction of 30% of income (optional). -SSCs are deductible from the PIT base. -Retain and report tax records (quarterly or annually). -May hire employees. -Must issue VAT receipts or other receipts to customers. |
5% (EUR 0 – 20 000). 5% - 15% (EUR 20 000 – 35 000). 15% (>EUR 35 000). |
2.Business certificate regime (BC regime) |
-Limited to certain business activities. -Limited to annual revenues cap of EUR 45,000. -SSCs are not deductible from PIT base. -No tax credit and no presumed expenses. -Taxpayers only need report turnover and not costs. -Tax liability set by and allocated to municipalities. -May not hire employees. |
Fixed lump-sum PIT payment. |
3.Standard employment contracts |
-Basic allowance. -SSCs not deductible from PIT base. |
20% (up to 60 monthly AW1). 32% (> 60 monthly AW1). |
4. Incorporation |
-Business chooses the form to realise their return |
Standard CIT rate is 15% Reduced CIT rates of 5% and 0% Tax rate on dividends is 15% |
Note: (1) AW refers to the SODRA average wage. The Several non-standard tax reliefs apply to the self-employed (these also apply to employment) including contributions to 3rd pillar pension funds, life insurance contributions, and certain 2nd pillar pension contributions and certain payments for studies.
Source: Sodra; VMI.
In the IA regime, the PIT rate is increasing. Under the IA regime, the PIT rate is applied to taxable income. The PIT rate ranges from 5% for taxable incomes up to EUR 20 000 to 15% for taxable incomes above EUR 35 000 (Table 5.1). The average effective PIT rate increases between taxable income of EUR 20 000 and EUR 35 000 as a result of the design (discussed later, see Figure 5.15).
In the IA regime, individuals can choose between declaring expenses and a presumed cost deduction. When taxing IA, all incomes related to IA are combined. Taxable IA income is calculated by deducting IA-related deductions. Deductions include IA-related expenses, non-taxable income, previous losses and SSCs (including health SSCs). Furthermore, IA taxpayers can choose between declaring actual expenses and opting for a presumed cost deduction of 30% of IA income (which includes SSCs and health SSCs).
In the IA regime, SSCs are deductible from the PIT base. For Lithuanian employees, SSCs are not deductible from the PIT base (in contrast to most OECD countries). For IA taxpayers, SSCs are deductible. For BC taxpayers, SSCs are not deductible (as are any other expenses for BC activities).
In the BC regime, individuals pay a fixed lump-sum payment. The tax liability is a fixed lump-sum PIT payment that is paid in advance when a taxpayer purchases the business certificate.
In the BC regime, the municipalities set the lump-sum payment and receive the PIT revenues. The amount of the lump-sum payment under the BC regime is set by the municipalities and is allocated to municipality budgets. In contrast, PIT revenues on other SE and employment income are set by central government (and allocated between central and local government).
The BC regime has an annual revenue cap. To be eligible for the BC regime, taxpayers must have annual revenues below EUR 45 000. Annual revenue exceeding the cap is taxed under the IA regime. The cap is equal to the VAT threshold in Lithuania so BC taxpayers usually do not have to register for VAT. Annual revenues include income from all activities with business certificate combined, except for rent from residential property, which is calculated separately.
Eligibility for the BC regime is limited to certain activities. To be eligible for the BC regime, taxpayers must operate in a specified list of activities set periodically by the government. Each activity requires a separate business certificate. The certificate is only valid for a specified location and time.
SSC rules
SSC rates for the self-employed are lower than for employees, particularly for the business certificate regime. Total SSC rates are highest for employees (21.29%), IA taxpayers (19.5%) followed by BC taxpayers (15.7%) (Table 5.2). When employer SSCs are excluded (which relate to unemployment, occupational accident and diseases and social tax), SSC rates are the same for employees and IA taxpayers. For BC taxpayers, SSC rates are lower as sickness and maternity SSCs are not included.
Table 5.2. SSC rates by organisational form
|
IA regime |
BC regime |
Employee |
---|---|---|---|
Total SSC rates |
19.5 |
15.7 |
21.29 |
Of which: |
|||
Excluding employer SSC rates |
19.5 |
15.7 |
19.5 |
Pension SSC rate |
8.72 |
8.72 |
8.72 |
Sickness SSC rate |
2.09 |
|
2.09 |
Maternity SSC rate |
1.71 |
|
1.71 |
Unemployment SSC rate |
|
|
(1.31) |
Occupational accidents and diseases SSC rate |
|
|
(0.16) |
Health SSC rate |
6.98 |
6.98 |
6.98 |
Social tax |
|
|
(0.32) |
Note: Employer SSCs are shown in brackets. Since 2021, self-employed persons at retirement age, receiving the old-age pension or with lost working capacity are exempt from paying SSCs.
Source: Sodra.
The SSC base for the self-employed is narrower than for employees, particularly for the business certificate regime. SSCs due are calculated by applying SSC rates (Table 5.2) to the SSC base. The SSC base is insurable income and differs by organisational form (Table 5.3). In the IA regime, the SSC base is 90% of taxable IA income (before SSCs are deducted). For health SSCs in the IA regime, there is an SSC floor so that insurable income cannot fall below the MMW. In the BC regime, insurable income is set at the MMW for pension SSCs and health SSCs (i.e. these are the only two SSC rates that apply to the BC). An SSC floor and ceiling apply to employees but not to the SE regimes (except for the health SSC in the IA regime).
Table 5.3. SSC tax base by organisational form
IA regime |
BC regime |
Employee |
- Insurable income set at 90% of taxable individual activity income. - SSC floor for health SSCs.1 |
- Insurable income set at MMW (for pension SSCs and health SSCs). |
- Insurable income set at gross wage and benefits. -SSC floor.2 - SSC ceiling.3 |
Note: 1. In the IA regime, for calculating health SSCs, there is an SSC floor such that insurable income cannot fall below MMW. 2. For calculating SSCs for employees, there is an employer SSC floor such that insurable income cannot be below MMW. If an employee’s income is below the MMW, employers pay the difference. 3. For employees, there is an SSC ceiling at incomes of 60 monthly AW in 2021. Above 60 monthly AW, there is a 0% contribution rate.
Source: Sodra.
The characteristics of the self-employed
Before considering the BC and IA regime in detail, this section provides an overview the income distributions and demographic characteristics across the regimes based on the microdata.
Applying the microdata to self-employment
Self-employed taxpayers are defined in the microdata as those with meaningful self-employment activity. To identify taxpayers with meaningful self-employment activity, self-employed taxpayers (SE) are defined as are non-pensioners (i.e. have no pension income) with SE income representing at least 15% of employment wage income plus SE income (Table 5.4). On this basis, there are 5,660 SE (8% of the three categories of taxpayers). Of these, 62% derive all of their income from SE and 38% from a combination of SE income and employment income. The SE group is further divided into the IA regime (64%) and BC regime (36%).
Comparing single income source groups is a useful empirical simplification. Since PIT applies to a wide range of incomes (e.g. employment, self-employment, dividends etc), a useful empirical simplification is to compare taxpayer groups with a single income source such as comparing ‘pure employees’ (i.e. employees with only employment income) with ‘pure self-employed’ (i.e. self-employed with only self-employment income).
Table 5.4. Defining self-employment in the microdata
Category |
Definition |
Number |
% |
---|---|---|---|
Total sample |
Total number of taxpayers in the sample. |
100 616 |
|
Total number of households in the sample. |
46 011 |
||
Sampling frame |
Total excluding taxpayers with no pension, employment or self-employment income. |
71 741 |
100% |
Of which: |
|||
Pensioners |
Total pension income (pension benefit + private pension + disability pension) is positive. |
27 400 |
38% |
Employees |
Not a pensioner, employment income is positive & self-employment share <15% of employment plus self-employment income. |
38 681 |
54% |
Self-employed |
Non-pensioner and self-employment income share is >=15%. |
5 660 |
8% |
Of which: |
|||
IA regime |
Taxpayers with an individual-activity certificate. |
3 649 |
64% |
Pure |
Individual-activity taxpayers with only self-employment income. |
1 011 |
|
BC regime |
Taxpayers with a business certificate. |
2 038 |
36% |
Pure |
Business certificate taxpayers with only self-employment income. |
815 |
Note: For the purposes of the analysis, taxpayers are divided into employees, self-employed and pensioners depending on their income source. The number of taxpayers in the categories do not sum to the total because a large number of taxpayers have no employment, SE or pension income (28 875). This may partly be explained as they are young and part of a household (mean age is 22 vs 43 in the general sample), they have other benefit sources not included or they represent data errors. If employment income were not set to be positive, the number of employees would be 67 556 and the numbers would sum correctly. The number of SE in the two regimes slightly exceeds the total number of SE individuals because taxpayers can be in more than one regime simultaneously.
Source: OECD analysis of microdata.
Self-employed incomes
Incomes are higher in the individual-activity regime than the business certificate regime due the cap on business certificate income. The income distribution of the two SE regimes is similar for most of the distribution but diverge at the highest incomes (Figure 5.4, Panel A), reflecting the smaller number of outlying high incomes in the BC regime (this is ensured by the BC regime annual revenue cap). Below the cap, BC taxpayers have modestly higher incomes for most of the distribution (Figure 5.4, Panel B). The IA regime has higher income inequality, reflected in a higher P80/20 ratio of 14 compared to 9 in the BC regime. IA and BC income refer to SE income derived under those regimes respectively and employee income refers to gross wage employment income.
However, when an adjustment is made for outliers and time spent working, business certificate taxpayers have higher self-employment income on average than individual activity taxpayers. IA taxpayers have higher mean SE income than BC taxpayers (+64%). A more appropriate comparison across the two regimes using median income shows that ‘pure’ BC taxpayers (i.e. SE income derived only from the BC regime) have 30% higher income than ‘pure’ IA taxpayers (i.e. SE income derived only from the IA regime). Furthermore, adjusting for the fact that BC taxpayers work about one-third less than the IA self-employed throughout the year (as proxied by the median number of months worked, see note Table 5.5), BC incomes are almost twice as high (+95%).
Compared to business certificate taxpayers, individual activity taxpayers earn higher average incomes from other sources such as employment and capital income. Other income sources tend to be higher on average in the IA regime including employment income (+23%) and dividends, interest and royalty income (+39%).
Table 5.5. Incomes by regime
Average gross monthly incomes, by income source and self-employment regime
IA regime |
BC regime |
% Difference |
|
---|---|---|---|
Self-employment income |
|||
Mean |
1 656 |
1 010 |
64% |
Median |
484 |
630 |
-23% |
Median for ‘pure self-employment’** |
419 |
708 |
-40% |
Median adjusted for months-worked* |
484 |
945 |
-49% |
Other income sources |
|||
Employment (mean) |
297 |
241 |
23% |
Financial (mean) |
142 |
180 |
-21% |
Rental (mean) |
15 |
16 |
-6% |
Dividend, interest and royalty (mean) |
32 |
23 |
39% |
Other (mean) |
285 |
74 |
285% |
Note: The IA, BC and employee groups include 3 649, 2 038 and 38 681 unique individuals respectively. For each of the respective regimes, self-employment income refers to income from individual activity only and business certificate only. *Self-employment months worked per year adjusted provides an indication of median income given the time spent working. It is calculated by multiplying median monthly income by 12 to give annual income and then dividing by the median number of months worked per year in that regime (which are 12.0 and 8.0 months in the individual activity and business certificate regimes respectively). **Pure self-employed refers to the self-employed with only self-employment income i.e. all other incomes are excluded (other incomes include employment, financial, rental, dividends, interest, royalties and other incomes).
Source: OECD analysis of microdata.
A high share of SE may be at risk of poverty. The IA taxpayer income distribution is positively skewed with many SE earning low incomes (Figure 5.5, Panel A). IA incomes are significantly below employee incomes. Half of IA taxpayers (54%) earn below the MMW compared to just one-quarter (25%) of employees. There is income bunching among employees at the MMW (Figure 5.5, Panel A).
A high share of part-time employees report very low incomes. Part-time (PT) employees3 working less than 12 months of the year and 3 months or less of the year earn much less than employees generally (Figure 5.5, Panel B). The share of PT employees in the former and latter groups earning below 10% of the AW is 20% and 32% respectively. Of taxpayers with both employment and SE income, about in 1 in 5 are PT employed (19%) according to the microdata. 2% are employed for 3 months of the year and have average income of EUR 753 (employment and SE income) vs EUR 2,187 for FT (i.e. 12 months of the year).
Self-employed demographics
Compared to employees, the self-employed are more likely to be male and married. Compared to employees, the SE are on average more likely to be male (+7% p.p.) and married (+9% p.p.) (Table 5.6). The age distribution and family structure between SE and employment are broadly similar.
The two self-employment regimes are broadly demographically similar, although business certificate taxpayers are more likely on average to be older, female, married and work part-time. Comparing between the two SE regimes, BC taxpayers are modestly more likely than IA taxpayers to be female (+4% p.p.) and married (+5% p.p.) (Table 5.6). BC taxpayers are more likely to work part-time (a median of 8 months annually compared to 12 months in the IA regime, see note from Table 5.5). BC taxpayers are older on average as group because there are less BC taxpayers under the age of 35 compared to the IA regime. The demographic characteristics of the SE regimes, and particularly the BC regime, have some similarities to the typical demographics of second-earners (as discussed previously, second-earners in Lithuania have strong work incentives at long-unemployment spells beyond 12 months). There is little statistical difference in family size and the prevalence of reported disability between the two SE regimes.
Table 5.6. Demographic characteristics by regime
IA regime |
BC regime |
Employees |
|
---|---|---|---|
% female |
42% |
46% |
50% |
% single |
29% |
21% |
32% |
% married |
59% |
64% |
53% |
% disabled |
6% |
6% |
4% |
% older (>= 60 years) |
6% |
7% |
7% |
% younger (< 35 years) |
34% |
26% |
34% |
% full-time employed |
22% |
19% |
67% |
Number in family household |
|||
1 |
16% |
16% |
18% |
2 |
18% |
18% |
19% |
3 |
23% |
25% |
25% |
4 |
23% |
23% |
22% |
5 |
10% |
10% |
9% |
Note: The IA, BC and employee groups include 3,649, 2,038 and 38,681 unique individuals respectively. Full-time employed refers to full-time employees.
Source: OECD analysis of microdata.
Business certificate regime
This section provides discussion, observations and recommendations on the design of the business certificate (BC) regime and its interaction with the individual-activity (IA) regime and standard employment. Its adherence to tax policy principles is discussed followed by the design of eligibility criteria, the determination of the tax liability, the role of migration from the regime and tax rate design. This section draws from a forthcoming OECD paper on the design of presumptive tax regimes ( (Mas-Montserrat et al., forthcoming[1])).
Eligibility design
The business certificate regime is a presumptive tax regime since it is not based on actual taxable income but rather on a presumed tax base. Presumptive tax regimes differ on the method used to make that presumption. In general, presumptive tax regimes do not aim to raise significant amounts of tax revenues but instead to improve tax compliance over the long term. This may justify tax revenue collection costs that exceed the tax revenues collected in the short term (Engelschalk, 2007[3]).
Revenue eligibility caps keep compliance costs low for taxpayers and enforcement costs low for tax admins but revenue measures can be relatively easily manipulated. Presumptive regimes commonly operate eligibility caps based on revenues (Thuronyi, 2004[4]). The design of revenue caps are simple, which keep compliance costs low for taxpayers and enforcement costs low for the tax admin. On the other hand, reported business revenues are relatively easy for taxpayers to manipulate.
The revenue cap influences the numbers of taxpayers in the self-employment regimes which in turn affects the levels of tax revenues and tax transparency for the authorities. Since SE move between regimes, the level at which the revenue cap is set will influence the numbers of SE in each regime, which in turn has tax policy implications. A high cap mechanically implies more BC taxpayers which means lower tax and compliance burdens for SEs but reduced tax revenues and information available for the authorities (Table 5.7) (BC taxpayers do not have to report costs reducing transparency and monitoring capabilities for the tax administration). Inversely, a lower cap implies more IA taxpayers which means higher tax and compliance burdens for SEs and increased tax revenues and transparency for the authorities (Table 5.7).
The revenue cap should be aligned and evolve with the capacity of the tax admin. From a tax admin perspective, the tax affairs of IA taxpayers are likely to have greater complexity and administrative burden than BC taxpayers (e.g. they report more information such as business costs on a more regular basis). Therefore, policies that shift the SE from the BC to the IA regime may increase the administrative burden on the tax admin (and vice versa). An example of such a policy is reducing the BC regime revenue eligibility cap (Table 5.7). Consequently, policies that shift the SE to the IA regime should be done with regard to the current and evolving capacity and capability of the tax admin to effectively manage and monitor the expected increase in the number of IA taxpayers arising from that policy.
Table 5.7. Stylised tax implications of adjusting the BC regime eligibility revenue cap
Higher revenue cap |
Lower revenue cap |
|
---|---|---|
Shifts self-employed to Taxpayer tax burden Taxpayer compliance burden Tax admin burden |
BC regime ↓ ↓ ↓ |
IA regime ↑ ↑ ↑ |
Tax admin revenues (PIT & SSCs) |
↓ |
↑ |
Note: For the purposes of this stylised example, tax admin transparency refers to reduced transparency in the BC regime because SEs do not need to report costs relative to the IA regime. Tax admin capacity refers to the reduced burden on the tax admin when the share of BC taxpayers (who have less complex tax affairs to manage) is greater than the share of IA taxpayers.
Source: OECD analysis.
The revenue cap may be too high, resulting in too many business certificate taxpayers and too few individual activity taxpayers (and lost tax revenues). The BC regime revenue cap is high in the context of the SE income distribution. 92% of IA regime SE have incomes below the cap and by design 100% of BC regime SE have incomes below the cap (Figure 5.6). Compared to selected presumptive regimes internationally (in USD PPP), the cap for the BC regime (USD 97 826) is above comparable regimes for unincorporated self-employed in Hungary (KATA regime, USD 77 499), similar to Italy (régime forfaitaire, USD 99 335) but below France (régime du micro-entrepreneur, USD 242 926). If the cap were cut to EUR 20000, about 20% of BC taxpayers would enter the IA regime (assuming no income responses to the cut). Given the wide tax burden gap between regimes (Figure 5.10), the cap should not be set too high as it extends BC eligibility too widely and reduces the standard IA regime thus undermining horizontal equity and tax revenues.
A high share of low-income SE in the IA regime may raise design rationale questions for the BC regime. Over half of IA taxpayers (54%) have incomes of 30% of AW or less. This may raise questions of the design rationale and targeting of the BC regime to the extent that it is aimed at supporting low-income SE in entering SE and growing as businesses with the eventual intention of migrating to the IA regime. Income comparisons between the regimes will also be affected by the BC regime being restricted to certain activities.
The alignment of the business certificate cap with the VAT threshold comes with advantages and drawbacks. The VAT registration threshold in Lithuania is high in international comparison (Figure 5.7). A case for alignment is that SE that have the capability to comply with VAT-related accounting and administration should also be able to maintain records and calculate their taxable profits under a standard regime (i.e. the IA regime). However, alignment implies that changes to PIT and VAT policy can jointly impact the regime. For example, VAT or PIT simplification measures or improvements in VAT refunds could make the IA regime more attractive, thus likely reducing the number of SE opting for the BC regime.
The business certificate sector eligibility criteria has the potential to produce vertical and horizontal inequities that might introduce competitive distortions. The BC regime is only available to SE operating in certain specified business activities, which could produce inequities. First, BC taxpayers with different turnover and costs but in the same sectors will face the same tax liability (‘vertical inequity’). Second, IA taxpayers that perform similar activities to BC taxpayers that are ineligible for the BC regime might have similar profits but face different tax burdens (‘horizontal inequity’). Third, taxpayers with similar profits just above and below the revenue cap but in different regimes would face different tax burdens (‘horizontal inequity’) (see Figure 5.9). An estimation of the extent of taxpayers that would be exposed to these various inequity risks could be investigated in the microdata.
Good practice suggests that revenue caps should generally be inflation-indexed. When the eligibility criteria is revenue, good practice is to index the cap to inflation to prevent erosion over time (Thuronyi, 2004[4]) (Bird and Wallace, 2004[5]) . Given currently high levels of inflation, non-indexation will shift SE from the BC to the IA regime. As this report recommends to lower the revenue eligibility cap, the cap could be lowered and subsequently inflation-indexed.
Tax liability design
The business certificate’s lump-sum payment has advantages, principally its simplicity. There are several approaches to determining the tax liability in presumptive tax regimes including applying lump-sum payments and tax rates. The lump-sum payment operated in the BC regime has several advantages (Figure 5.11) as follows:
1. It is transparent and predictable, resulting in low compliance costs for taxpayers and low enforcement costs for the tax admin.
2. It is a low payment in relative and absolute terms, which helps encourage informal workers to enter the regime and to ensure voluntary compliance.
3. Since the tax is set by the municipalities, there is no computation cost for BC taxpayers.
4. Since BC taxpayers do not have to declare costs (only turnover), the administrative costs of record-keeping and accounting are low.
5. It avoids creating disincentives for businesses to grow since the tax payment remains fixed as income increases.
The lump-sum payment has several drawbacks, particularly its regressivity.
1. It is regressive and places a higher tax burden on the poorest SE by treating all taxpayers equally regardless of their income and ability to pay.
2. It is regressive relative to alternative approaches to determining tax liability in presumptive regimes. A lump-sum payment is regressive relative to a lump-sum payment that is differentiated by sector of activity or within turnover bands. It is also regressive relative to proportional or progressive tax rates levied on turnover. While such alternatives can improve progressivity they also come with several drawbacks including increased complexity.
3. A fixed amount may not allow for the tax burden to fluctuate when economic activity and incomes drops thus creating cash flow challenges (ILO, 2021[6]). However, the government can opt to make periodic adjustments to the amount.
4. It may create an entry barrier for businesses that do not make profits as losses cannot be offset against future liabilities.
5. Given the population of lump-sum payments in countries that implement them, they may be difficult to abolish (Bucci, 2020[7]).
An alternative to the lump-sum payment approach is a proportional tax rate on turnover. Compared to the lump-sum payment, a proportional tax rate results in a tax liability that is linear relative to revenue, making it less regressive than the lump-sum payment. Since taxpayers in the BC regime already declare turnover (but not costs), the operation of a proportional tax rate on turnover would add a minimal tax compliance burden in terms of computing the tax liability. However, proportional tax rates have drawbacks including that reported turnover measures are relatively easy to manipulate, which introduces non-compliance risk.
The proportional tax rate on turnover could vary by business sector profitability. Differentiated tax rates across sectors would allow levying a higher rate on the activities that are on average more profitable. This would prevent highly profitable businesses facing a low presumptive tax burden who would face a tax-induced incentive to remain in the BC regime and not migrate into the IA regime. On the other hand, differentiated sector tax rates are based on average profitability rates which means that high profit business in a sector with low average profits will not be highly taxed. Differentiated sector tax rates also produce a tax-induced incentive for businesses to reclassify their sectoral status to more lightly taxed sectors.
Table 5.8. The business certificate’s lump-sum payment has several advantages
Approaches to determining tax liability in presumptive regimes, selected advantages and drawbacks
Advantages |
Drawbacks |
|
---|---|---|
Lump-sum amount |
- Transparent & predictable - Low relative & absolute amounts - Low computation cost - Low administrative burden - Low disincentives to grow |
- High tax burden on poorest - Less regressive options exist - May not allow for economic fluctuations - Possible barrier for loss-making firms - Challenging to abolish |
Proportional tax rate on turnover |
- Less regressive linear tax liability - Low computation cost |
- Turnover is easy to manipulate - May not capture profitability well - Can discourage investment if applied to indicators (e.g. no. employees) |
Source: Adapted from forthcoming OECD research on presumptive regimes.
Migration from the business certificate regime
The design of the tax system should provide businesses with an incentive to migrate from the business certificate to the individual-activity regime. A smooth transition from a presumptive to a standard regime might be achieved by introducing simplified tax provisions and administrative procedures in the standard regime (e.g. reduced rates, simplified accounting, simplification of VAT-related administrative procedures) (Engelschalk, 2007[3]). However, such features might need to be time-limited to prevent potential disadvantages such as bunching effects and artificial closing and reopening of business activities.
However, a sharp rise in the marginal tax wedge as taxpayer’s transition to the individual-activity regime is likely to deter migration. Up to the BC regime eligibility cap, METRs remain flat and close to zero as taxes remain unchanged with higher incomes (Figure 5.8) (the fluctuation in the METRs is due to fluctuations in the average PIT reported on the tax records within the income bands and sample size issues). Once the cap is reached, the SE enter the IA regime and then face higher METRs (Figure 5.8) due to higher SSCs and a progressive PIT (see Figure 5.10).
Income bunching below the business certificate eligibility cap reflects the disincentive to migrate to the individual-activity regime and the administrative burden of VAT registration. The share of BC self-employed spikes just below the BC regime cap and VAT threshold of EUR 45 000 (Figure 5.9). This suggests that some BC taxpayers may be under-reporting incomes to avoid VAT registration or the IA regime or a combination of both. BC taxpayers that exceeded the threshold would migrate to the IA regime and face higher average and marginal tax burdens in this income range (Figure 5.8) in addition to higher administrative burdens associated with VAT compliance. If taxpayers were to supress reported incomes, which they have an incentive to do, there could be additional undetected income bunching. The sample tax record data indicate that 3.9% of BC report SE income between EUR 40 000 and EUR 45 000, which implies approximately 3 500 taxpayers nationally in that income range.4 The share of IA taxpayers is greater between EUR 40 000 and EUR 45 000 than it is between EUR 45 000 and EUR 50 000 (Figure 5.9), suggesting that some IA taxpayers could be misreporting incomes to avoid VAT registration. These interpretations remain suggestive rather than conclusive in the absence of the larger sample size of the full tax record data and multivariate analysis that controls for multiple variables. As further work, longitudinal tax record data could be employed to track and identify the type of self-employed that switch from the BC to the IA regime (and vice versa) and the role of the tax burden in that decision.
The tax burden in the business certificate regime is low relative to standard employment and individual activity (except at low incomes)
Effective PIT rates in the business certificate regime are below those in the individual activity regime across the income distribution based on the tax record data. In the BC regime, average effective PIT rates (i.e. business certificate PIT paid as a share of business certificate income on the tax records) are lower than the IA regime across all gross incomes (Figure 5.10).
However, a relatively high SSC floor in the business certificate regime implies that low-income self-employed could prefer the individual activity regime. Due to a relatively high SSC floor in the BC regime (the base is set at the MMW), the average tax wedge under the BC regime is higher than under the IA regime at low incomes (below 30% of AW) but becomes progressively lower at higher incomes (comparing Figure 5.10, Panels A and B) (note that very low incomes are not shown but examined later in Figure 5.12). This occurs because SSCs are calculated as a share of income in the IA regime and PIT rates increase at higher incomes whereas SSCs and PIT remain flat in the BC regime leading to a decline in the average tax wedge. These tax burdens imply that the self-employed may prefer the IA regime at low incomes and the BC regime at middle and higher incomes up the revenue cap of EUR 45 000. Since many SE earn low incomes (47% of IA SE earn incomes less than 30% of the employee AW based on the microdata), a significant share of low-income SE may prefer the IA regime at low incomes. In the IA regime, both hypothetical and empirical PIT and average tax wedges are calculated for robustness based on the tax rules and the tax record data respectively (see note in Figure 5.10). The IA regime calculations are based on self-employed who opt for the presumed cost deduction (see note in Figure 5.10).
The average effective tax wedge in the business certificate is far below that of employees at all incomes. The average effective tax wedge for employees always exceeds those of both self-employment regimes driven by higher employee and employer SSCs at low incomes (Figure 5.10, Panel C) and significantly higher PIT rates (Figure 5.10, Panel A).
Average effective tax wedges are high at very low incomes across several organisational forms driven by different SSC floors. At very low incomes between 0 - 10% of AW (not shown in Figure 5.10), the average tax wedges are similarly high across all organisational forms due to different SSC floors. In the BC regime, the average tax wedge is 71% (due to the minimum SSC base set at MMW and the lump-sum payment), in the IA regime 63% (due to the minimum health SSC floor) and for employees 70% (due to the employer SSC floor). Note that the employer SSC floor does not apply to all SE because not all SE are obliged to pay SSCs (e.g. SE that have reached retirement age, SE receiving the social insurance old-age pension).
The income distribution shows that the lowest income self-employed prefer the standard individual-activity regime to the business certificate regime. As shown in Figure 5.12, the higher average tax wedge in the BC regime relative to the IA regime at low incomes could lead to the lowest income SE preferring the standard IA regime to the presumptive BC regime. When the income distribution of the IA and BC regimes is overlaid alongside the average tax wedges in the two regimes, a high share of the lowest income self-employed are in the IA regime both in absolute terms and relative to the numbers in the BC regime (Figure 5.12). This may suggest that some SE are choosing the IA regime over the BC regime to avail of a lower tax burden. A range of other factors may play a role in the low-income SE opting for the IA regime including restrictive eligibility criteria for entering the BC regime such as the list of eligible activities.
The tax burden on the lowest income self-employed is high relative to reported self-employment incomes. Although the tax wedge is higher in the BC than the IA regime at low incomes, it remains high in both regimes, which could produce a disincentive for the SE to formalise their business in either regime. There is however a tax vacation for new IA taxpayers to encourage formal work. The high tax wedges may also be a result of low reported SE incomes. The absolute PIT and SSCs are quite low. If the true incomes of the SE were higher than those reported, which could be the case in some cases given relatively high reported informality in Lithuania generally, the true tax burdens faced by the SE would be lower.
Illustrative simulations of reform options
Aligning the average PIT rates in the business certificate regime with those in the individual-activity regime would raise average effective PIT rates and PIT revenues. An illustrative indication of PIT revenues in the BC regime can be estimated across the income distribution by applying the average PIT rates in Figure 5.12 to the total BC income of EUR 823 million in 2019 (see note in Figure 5.13). This approach gives a reasonable estimated PIT revenues of EUR 7.8 million compared to actual BC PIT revenues of EUR 8.5 million in 2019. To give an indication of aligning the tax burden between regimes, the average effective PIT rates in the IA regime can be applied to total BC income by income band, which shows that average PIT rates would increase across the income distribution and PIT revenues would increase by a factor of 4.7 (Figure 5.13).
An illustrative simulation of a low proportional tax rate on turnover in the business certificate regime serves to highlights that the existing lump-sum payment amount produces very low tax effective rates in the regime. To illustrate the proportional tax rate approach in the BC regime, a 3% tax rate levied on BC turnover would raise the effective PIT rate on BC taxpayers across all incomes and increase PIT revenues by a factor of over 3 (Figure 5.13) (note that PIT revenues are not increasing with higher average PIT rates at higher incomes due to fewer BC taxpayers at higher incomes). The proportional tax rate on turnover serves to highlight how even a low proportional tax rate on turnover would substantially increase effective PIT rates and PIT revenues compared to the existing approach.
Replacing the fixed lump-sum payment in the BC regime with a 3% proportional tax rate on turnover would increase total PIT revenues by 0.5%. According to modelling in EUROMOD, the reform would produce relatively high increases in PIT revenues in lower equivalised household disposable income deciles (Figure 5.14). This is partly because most BC taxpayers earn very low incomes and pay very low PIT. The reform would increase income inequality by 0.0556 percentage points as measured by the S80/S20 ratio.
Adherence of the business certificate regime to tax policy principles and tax liability reform options
The business certificate regime violates the principle of horizontal equity. The BC regime has very low tax burdens on taxpayers with similar incomes relative to the IA regime (Figure 5.10). This violates the principle of horizontal equity which states that similar (in this case, on the basis of income) SE taxpayers should be taxed similarly. The departure from the horizontal equity principle in the BC regime requires a justifying rationale. It follows that the significant tax burden differential between the regimes requires a correspondingly significant justifying rationale. A rationale may be that BC taxpayers face different economic realities to other SE forms that justify a lower tax burden. However, this does not seem to be supported based on broadly similar demographic characteristics between the SE regimes (Table 5.5 and Table 5.6) and higher median incomes in the BC regime when adjustments are made for time spent working (Table 5.4).
The departure from horizontal equity has implications for tax neutrality. The current design of the BC regime is likely to violate the principle of tax neutrality by influencing organisational form decisions. IA taxpayers have a tax-induced incentive to reclassify their sector of activity to fit those eligible for the BC regime and to supress their income below the BC cap. Employees have a tax-induced incentive to reclassify as SE and enter the BC regime. These tax arbitrage opportunities risk higher numbers of taxpayers entering the BC regime than would otherwise be the case, which could undermine tax revenues and equity by placing a higher tax burden on employees. The costs of this tax arbitrage produced by the BC regime design should be weighed against the justification for non-neutrality including encouraging the growth of small business and formality.
The revenue eligibility cap could be reduced to target only micro-businesses. The revenue cap is high relative to SE incomes. 92% of IA regime SE have incomes below the cap and by design 100% of BC regime SE have incomes below the cap (Figure 5.6). For example, a reduced cap to EUR 20 000 would narrow the scale of the BC regime (improving horizontal equity) and could mechanically migrate about 20% of higher-income BC taxpayers to the IA regime (an even lower cap could also be considered based on the income distribution). This would raise PIT and SSC revenues and increase transparency for the tax admin (i.e. as costs are not reported in the business certificate).
There are several reform options for raising taxes in the business certificate regime including the following.
1. Increase the lump-sum payment. The existing tax liability approach used in the BC regime of a lump-sum PIT payment set by the municipalities could be increased at the level of the municipalities. In this case, the current design would be retained and only the PIT payment would be increased.
2. Increase the lump-sum payment and incorporate SSCs within the payment, although this approach has limitations. In presumptive regimes, a single tax payment often incorporates SSCs. Including SSCs in a single payment can reduces administrative costs and support tax compliance. Empirical evidence has found that a presumptive tax regime can induce businesses to formalise with the tax administration without necessarily formalising its employees in the social security system (Teixeira, 2021[8]) (Díaz et al., 2018[9]). In the BC regime, the lump-sum payment does not include SSCs, which are calculated separately. As part of increasing the lump-sum PIT payment, the SSC contributions for the BC regime could be consolidated within the lump-sum tax payment. This would have the advantage of simplifying the compliance burden on BC taxpayers. On the other hand, including SSCs within the lump-sum payment would more explicitly break the link between SSCs paid and benefits received, which is an argument for keeping SSCs outside of the presumptive regime. This approach would also raise the question of whether the SSCs should be collected at the local or government level.
3. Replace the lump-sum payment with a proportional tax on turnover and align the tax burden with the individual-activity regime. The lump-sum PIT amount could be replaced with a proportional tax on turnover over the medium-term. The tax burden could be more closely aligned with the tax burden in the IA regime to reduce vertical inequity and arbitrage opportunities. The tax burden would not necessarily need to be exactly aligned with that of the IA regime but reducing the tax burden gap would reduce tax arbitrage opportunities. The appropriate tax burden and tax rates could be set based on an evaluation of the profitability of SE businesses in Lithuania. If profitability differs across sectors, a sector-based approach could be considered.
4. Administrative and accounting training may help to smooth the transition to the individual-activity regime. The BC regime is only valid for a specific time. A BC can be issued for a maximum of one year but can be as short as 5 days. Business certificates can then be renewed. When regimes have eligibility periods such as the BC regime, providing supports such as book-keeping or accounting training may help taxpayers to transition to the IA regime (Engelschalk, 2007[3]).
Individual-activity regime
This section provides discussion, observations and recommendations on the design of the individual-activity (IA) regime and its interaction with standard employment. Its adherence to tax policy principles is discussed followed by the design of eligibility criteria, the determination of the tax liability, the role of migration from the regime and tax rate design. The analysis presented for the IA regime includes self-employed farmers and non-farmers. Since the tax rules differ for farmers, farmers are briefly discussed separately at the end of this section.
Design of the tax credit
In the IA regime, a tax credit is available that cuts the effective PIT rate, particularly for those on lower and middle incomes. Under the IA regime, a tax credit is available based on taxable IA income where there is a legal distinction between taxable income and taxable IA income. The latter is more narrowly defined to include only income and exemptions related specifically to IA (i.e. other income such as income from BC and other exemptions unrelated to IA are excluded). The formula for calculating the tax credit (see equation 1) includes which is annual IA taxable income and which is an identifier set equal to 1 if exceeds EUR 20 000 and 0 otherwise. As a share of IA taxable income, the tax credit is 10% for taxable incomes up to EUR 20 000 and steadily reduced thereafter until it no longer applies at EUR 35 000. Without the tax credit, an IA taxpayer pays an effective tax rate of 15% on taxable IA income. For those with taxable income below EUR 20 000 where the full tax credit applies, the effective tax rate is reduced to 5%. For those with higher taxable income between EUR 20 000 and EUR 35 000, the effective tax rate is higher ranging from 5 to 15%.
In the IA regime, statutory PIT rates are always lower than in standard employment. As a result of the tax credit, the statutory PIT rate in the IA regime ranges from 5% for incomes up to EUR 20 000 to 15% for incomes above EUR 35 000. Statutory PIT rates for employees are always higher at 20% up to 60 monthly AW (i.e. EUR 104 278 in 2020) and 32% above that. Effective PIT rates on IA taxpayers are also lower at most incomes (see Figure 5.17, Panel A).
The IA regime PIT design will produce rising METRs. As the tax credit is tapered in the IA regime, increasingly higher effective PIT rates are paid on total taxable income (up to the max PIT rate of 15%). As a matter of design, this is unlike in a standard progressive PIT system where a higher PIT rate is levied only on that part of income above a higher PIT bracket. Consequently, the tax credit design will produce rising METRs for IA taxpayers because earning an additional euro of income faces a higher statutory tax rate that applies to the entire taxable income (rather than just the part of income above a higher PIT bracket).
Design of presumptive cost deduction
The presumed cost deduction does not appear to be sufficiently generous to be preferred to declaring actual costs. The presumed cost deduction includes SSC payments that IA taxpayers are required to pay. IA regime SSC rates of 19.5% levied on 63% of gross earnings imply effective SSC rates of 12.3% on gross income. Consequently, the presumptive cost deduction can be represented in two separate deduction components - SSCs (12.3% of gross income) and a standard deduction (17.7% of gross income). The latter deduction component corresponds to the input costs of operating a business. Actual costs faced by small individual SE may exceed 17.7% of income. Indeed, a 30% presumptive cost deduction is low when compared with selected OECD countries (it ranges from 34 – 70% in France and from 14 – 60% in Italy conditional on economic activity5).
However, a majority opt for the presumed cost deduction, which presents a puzzle. Take-up of the presumed cost deduction is high among IA taxpayers (83%) compared to those opting for declaring deductions (17%). One reason could be the increased admin and compliance costs associated of maintaining tax and accounting records that can be disproportionately burdensome for smaller SEs. A further reason is that a majority of IA taxpayers are non-VAT registered (over 9 in 10 report income below the VAT threshold) and therefore cannot benefit from VAT deductions by declaring deductions. Indeed, IA taxpayers with incomes above the VAT threshold opt for the presumed cost deduction less on average. Additionally, few SEs may make tax losses that can then be carried forward to reduce future taxes, which would increase the incentive to declare actual costs. From a non-compliance perspective, it is possible that the presumed cost deduction is chosen as a means to under-report income and minimise information provided to the tax admin instead of declaring actual costs and invoices which would increase information available to the tax admin and might allow for detecting such sales suppression. As a stylised example, if an SE opts for the presumed cost deduction and suppresses sales at the same rate as shadow economy as a share of GDP (i.e. 23% in 2021),6 taxable income would be the same as if they declared actual costs of 46% of gross income. Therefore, in a high informality SE environment reflected in sales suppression, the presumed cost deduction provides an effective deduction that exceeds 30% of income.
Design of SSCs
IA taxpayers can deduct SSCs to reduce their tax burden whereas employees cannot deduct SSCs. The non-deductibility of SSCs from the PIT base for employees implies that employees face higher tax burdens relative to IA taxpayers who can deduct SSCs from gross income (either implicitly through the presumed cost deduction or explicitly by declaring actual costs).
IA taxpayers face the same statutory SSC rates as employees. In the IA regime, the total SSC rate is 19.5%, which is comprised of a general SSC rate of 12.52% (that covers pension, sickness and maternity) and a health SSC rate of 6.98% (Table 5.2). The IA SSC rate is above the BC regime (15.7%) and the same as for employees when employer SSCs are excluded (i.e. 19.5%).
However, IA taxpayers face a narrower SSC base than employees which results in significantly lower effective SSC rates. In the IA regime, the SSC base is 90% of taxable IA income (before SSCs are deducted). For IA taxpayers that claim the presumed cost deduction of 30%, which is most IA taxpayers (83%), the effective SSC base is then 63% of gross income. For IA taxpayers that opt to declare expenses the effective SSC base could be even lower. By contrast, employees pay employee SSCs on 100% of their gross income. The employee SSC base is not reduced by the BA that employees claim.
Compared to employees, the SSC ceiling for IA taxpayers is introduced at a lower income and is more broadly applied (it covers health SSCs) which cuts the tax burden on high-income self-employed relative to high-income employees. For employees, the employee SSC ceiling is 5 annual AW since 2021 and the ceiling excludes health SSCs. In the IA regime, the SSC ceilings is lower at 3.6 annual AW in 2022 and the ceiling applies to health SSCs (unlike for employees) (note that the SSC ceiling cannot apply to the BC regime as it exceeds the BC regime income eligibility cap). For IA taxpayers, the SSC ceilings produce a gradual reduction in the AETR and a sharp fall in the METR at about 384% of the AW which would not occur in the absence of the SSC ceilings. For employees, the SSC ceiling occurs later at 482% of AW and does not change the AETR because it coincides with the simultaneous introduction of the top PIT rate.
The expiration of the health SSC floor produces an increased marginal tax wedge but few IA taxpayers appear to respond to it. As the health SSC floor is lifted in the IA regime and there is an increase in the marginal tax wedge, there is some evidence of SE income bunching but it is very limited in terms of the share of SE (Figure 5.16).
There may be scope to harmonise SSC and health SSC payments on a monthly basis in the IA regime. IA taxpayers currently pay SSCs on an annual basis and health SSCs on a monthly basis. Converting the annual SSC payment to a monthly payment (assuming automated or directly deducted payments with no additional tax compliance burden for taxpayers) would have the advantage of reducing the risk of SSC arrears to the tax admin and providing taxpayers with a clearer picture of their financial situation throughout the year as payments are made monthly.
The tax burden in the IA regime is low relative to employment
Most IA taxpayers face an effective PIT rate of 3.5%, far below that of employees. With regard to the PIT base, IA taxpayers pay PIT on taxable income reduced by deductions (presumptive or declared) whereas employees pay PIT on gross income reduced by the basic allowance. This results in IA taxpayers having higher effective PIT rates than employees at low incomes below about one-third of AW (i.e. the BA means low-income employees pay no PIT) but higher effective PIT rates above that (Figure 5.17, Panel A). Most employees across the income distribution face high and flat effective PIT rates (Figure 5.17, Panel A). For example, effective PIT rates for employees are 9% at 1/2 the AW, 16% at the AW and 20% at twice the AW (Figure 5.17, Panel A). With the exception of low incomes where the BA exempts employees from paying any PIT, IA taxpayers face significantly lower effective PIT rates at all incomes.
IA taxpayers face an average effective tax wedge lower than employees at all incomes. While the shape of the average tax wedge across the income distribution is similar between IA and employees (i.e. it is relatively compressed and flat), it is significantly lower for IA, particularly at incomes above half the AW. The IA tax wedge ranges from about 1/3 to 2/3 of the employee tax wedge for most of the distribution (Figure 5.17, Panel B). In other words, between 50% and 150% of the AW, the employee tax wedge is about 21 percentage points higher than the IA tax wedge. At low incomes, the IA tax wedge is relatively higher due to the health SSC floor but it remains below that of employees. Due to the BA and the exclusion of employer SSCs, the net personal average tax rate (NPATR) for employees is below the IA average tax wedge up to about 1/4 of the AW.
The microdata confirm that PIT rates and average effective tax rates are lower for IA taxpayers than employees. Compared to the previous hypothetical models (Figure 5.17), when microdata is used to calculate the effective PIT rate and AETR (average effective tax wedge as calculated in Figure 5.18) similar patterns emerge – IA taxpayers face lower tax burdens than employees (Figure 5.18) (for the purposes of the analysis, only 84% of IA that opt for the presumed cost deduction are included and the AETR for employees is calculated using Taxing Wages 2021, see note (Figure 5.18).
High-income IA taxpayers face rising METRs as the tax credit tapers. For employees, the first spike in the METR (marginal tax wedge as calculated in Figure 5.18) occurs as employees first start to pay PIT and the second spike occurs as the max BA starts to taper-out. Since many employees earn incomes at 1/3 and 1/2 the AW, the income-bunching risk from high METRs is greater. For the IA, over the same income range, the METR is by contrast relatively flat (with a modest increase as the health SSC floor expires) suggesting limited incentives to distort behaviour (Figure 5.17, Panel C). At higher incomes however, the design of the SE regime produces elevated METRs. As the tax credit is tapered at taxable income of EUR 20 000 (i.e. 170% of AW), the IA METR jumps and steadily rises before dropping as the tax credit expires (at EUR 35 000 i.e. 297% of AW). The METR drops further at 384% of AW as the SSC ceiling is introduced.
The IA regime design and the self-employment income distribution
Few IA taxpayers will face high METRs so disincentives to progress in work will be limited. The increasing METRs in the IA regime will reduce incentives to progress in work. However, few IA taxpayers earn incomes within the income range where METRs are high (Figure 5.18) so the negative impacts will be limited.
Similarly, as few higher income SE earn sufficient income to face higher PIT rates, the progressivity introduced by the tax credit will be limited. The tax credit design cannot achieve the goal of promoting progressivity because it does not appear to have been designed to reflect the actual IA income distribution (Figure 5.18). In the IA regime, a majority (85%) face an effective PIT rate on gross income of 3.5% with only a minority (4%) facing the 10.5% PIT rate on gross income or a rate in-between (8%) (Figure 5.18, Panel A).7
Adherence of the individual-activity regime to tax policy principles
The IA regime design may produce horizontal inequity (i.e. IA taxpayers with similar incomes to employees face lower tax burdens). The lower IA tax burden is driven by a range of tax design features that advantage SE over employment. These include lower statutory PIT rates, narrower PIT and SSC bases, deductible SSCs and a lower and broader SSC ceiling. These design features violate the principle of horizontal equity by taxing similar taxpayers differently. In the absence of a strong rationale, they may be unequitable.
The IA regime may not be tax neutral (i.e. it may encourage tax arbitrage from employment to SE). The aforementioned design features of the IA regime may violate tax neutrality as the tax design encourages employees to reclassify as SE to avail of a reduced tax burden. For example, an employee may be able to do the same work for their employer at a reduced tax burden by incorporating as an IA taxpayer. This tax arbitrage opportunity risks higher numbers of employees entering the IA regime than would otherwise be the case, potentially undermining tax revenues by placing a higher tax burden on the employee taxpaying population.
Justifying rational exist for some departure from these principles for the SE but they should be weighed against arbitrage and tax revenue risks. Justifying rationale for why SE may be taxed lower than similar income employees could include that the authorities prefer to encourage small business growth, SE face greater job uncertainty in addition to reduced employment and entitlement rights. These rationale should be weighed against the likelihood and tax revenue risks of tax arbitrage opportunities produced by the tax burden differentials between the organisational forms.
Reform options
A number of tax policy reforms could be considered. To mitigate against the aforementioned challenges of horizontal inequity and tax non-neutrality between the IA regime and employment, there is a scope for tax policy reform. While perfect alignment of the tax burden between the IA regime and employment may not be preferable (given justifying rationale for lower burdens on SE) or indeed politically feasible, tax policies that reduce misalignment will reduce the challenges of horizontal inequity and tax non-neutrality. A number of such tax policy reforms that could be considered are as follows:
1. Raise the PIT rate in the IA regime to better align with the PIT rate faced by employees. Statutory PIT rates in the IA regime are always lower than PIT rates on employees. Effective PIT rates in the IA regime are lower than on employees at most incomes. To support fairness and reduce tax arbitrage between employment and SE, the IA PIT rate could be aligned with the standard 20% PIT rate for employees. This could be achieved by reforming the tax credit design by cutting the tax credit threshold (i.e. currently EUR 20 000) or the tax credit (i.e. currently 10%).
2. The appropriate PIT rate could set based on an evaluation of profits in the IA regime, but the data availability for a rigorous evaluation may be lacking. An evaluation of profitability or the ability to pay might be challenging given the high take-up of the presumptive cost deduction which, from the perspective of data availability, implies that the tax admin likely has limited tax record information on the costs of business operations in the IA regime. An analysis of IA taxpayers that do declare actual tax returns is likely to suffer from selection bias so that a representative evaluation would be challenging.
3. Broaden the SSC base in the IA regime to better align with that of employment. IA taxpayers face a narrower SSC base (of 63% of gross income under the presumed cost deduction) than employees (of 100% of gross income). The IA SSC base could be broadened to better align with the employee SSC base. One option could be to set the IA SSC base at 100% of taxable income instead of 90% of taxable income so that the effective SSC base becomes 70% of gross income. In this case, IA taxpayers would continue to pay lower SSCs as they face the same statutory SSC rates as employees.
4. Align the SSC deductibility rules between the IA regime and employment. To reflect the costs of inputs in operating a business, IA taxpayers can deduct costs. The employee equivalent is the costs of going to work which form part of the rationale for a basic allowance. However, IA taxpayers can further deduct SSCs (presumed or declared) whereas employees cannot, which implies reduced tax burdens for IA taxpayers. In the absence of a justifying rationale, SSC deductibility could be afforded to employees and SEs more equally. This could be achieved directly by disallowing IA taxpayers from deducting pension SSCs. The SSC pension benefits of employees could continue to remain untaxed (as employees have effectively already been taxed through higher PIT).
5. The SSC ceiling design between SE and employees could be equalised to reduce tax arbitrage opportunities. There does not appear to be a strong rationale for lower SSC ceilings on IA which imply that high-income IA benefit from reduced SSC burdens. Raising the IA SSC ceiling to align with that of employees would increase the SSC burden on high-income IA and raise SSC revenues, albeit the SSC revenue impact would be limited as few IA have very high incomes. Aligning the SSC ceiling would reduce arbitrage opportunities for high-income employees to incorporate as SE to reduce their tax burden. Aligning the scope of the SSC ceilings (i.e. the employee SSC ceiling excludes health SSCs but the SE ceiling includes health SSCs) would similarly reduce tax arbitrage opportunities. SSC ceilings should be applied on a combined income, irrespective of the type of activity form which the income is derived.
6. The IA regime tax credit design should be aligned with the SE income distribution in mind. The tax credit in the IA regime could be better designed. From the perspective of achieving PIT progressivity, too few IA taxpayers report incomes within the income range where it has been set. From the perspective of incentives, of the few taxpayers that it affects, a rising METR may discourage business growth.
7. Consideration could be given to abolishing the presumptive cost deduction as it weakens the tax admin’s capacity to successfully monitor and enforce compliance. Despite the presumed cost deduction seeming insufficiently generously to be preferred to declaring actual costs, more than 4 in 5 IA taxpayers (83%) opt for it based on an estimate from the microdata. There are advantages to a presumed cost deduction including simplicity for taxpayers and the tax admin. However, a main drawback of a majority of IA taxpayers opting for the presumptive cost deduction is that the tax admin has limited transparency on the actual operations and costs of business within the IA regime. On top of limited transparency in the IA regime, Lithuania operates a presumptive BC regime where costs are not required to be reported. Taking the two unincorporated SE regimes together, this implies that the tax admin has cost information on only about 1 in 10 businesses (13%8). This lack of information may weaken the tax admin’s capacity to successfully monitor and tackle compliance in the IA regime.
8. There may be a tax-induced incentive to switch from employment to self-employment as incomes increase. If taxpayers responded to the net personal average tax rate (Figure 5.17, Panel B), they would face a tax-induced incentive to be employed at incomes up to about 1/4 of the AW and to enter the IA regime once income increased beyond that. The income distribution data show significant shares of part-time (PT) employees in this income range (Figure 5.5). Although a high share of PT employees report very low incomes, this does not necessarily imply that they face poverty risks as they have high incomes on per month basis. For example, it could be speculated that some employees intentionally work PT and report low incomes to avail of a lower tax burden and then switch to more lightly taxed SE when income rises. Such an organisational arrangement is made possible by the tax rules which allow individuals to simultaneously be employed, have a business certificate and an individual certificate. However, the extent of this arbitrage behaviour remains unclear in the absence of a more comprehensive analysis of switching between organisational forms using longitudinal microdata. We leave this for future work.
Simulating reforms
The tax burdens in the IA regime can be simulated and compared with employment for several potential tax reforms by applying the SE tax rules to income and taxes on the microdata. SE face lower tax rates than employees because they can deduct business costs from their income (for employees, the costs are already borne by their employer). To account for this difference methodologically and improve comparability, IA costs are set at zero (i.e. the presumed cost deduction is reduced from 30% to 0%. Note that this raises the tax burden on IA thus narrowing the gap with employees). The simulation informs the extent of the tax burden alignment between IA taxpayers and employees on several tax reform options as follows:
1. Cutting the tax credit threshold to zero would broadly align the PIT burden with employees. The effective PIT rate for the IA would broadly align with employees if the tax credit (TC) threshold was reduced from EUR 20 000 to EUR 0 (Figure 5.19, Panel A). This occurs as a TC threshold of zero corresponds to a PIT rate of 5% from when income is first earned that then steadily increases up to a PIT rate of 15% (if the TC were not set to zero, the PIT rate is flat at 5% up to 170% of the AW).
2. Removing the deductibility of SSCs from the IA regime would modestly raise the tax burden, particularly on high earners. Employees cannot deduct SSCs from the PIT base. If non-deductibility of SSCs were extended to IA taxpayers that opt for the presumptive cost deduction (i.e. implying a presumptive cost deduction of 17.7%), it would modestly raise the IA tax burden across the income distribution, notably at higher incomes when the health SSC floor has expired (Figure 5.19, Panel B, SE (3), see Figure notes).
3. Broadening the IA SSC base would not alter the tax burden significantly. If the IA SSC base was broadened from 90% to 100% of taxable income, the tax burden would increase but only very modestly (Figure 5.19, Panel B, SE (2), see Figure notes).
4. Aligning the IA PIT rate with the employee PIT rate would meaningfully shift the IA tax burden upwards but it would remain below that of employment. Increasing the PIT rate to 20% would shift the IA tax burden upwards relatively uniformly across the income distribution (Figure 5.19, Panel C, SE (5), see Figure notes) (following the methodology to increase comparability in chart A, chart C sets the presumptive cost deduction to zero, SE (4)). The distributional pattern of the tax burden would remain similar.
5. Aligning the IA PIT rate and simultaneously cutting the tax credit threshold to zero would better align the tax burden and the tax burden distributional shape with that of employment. Increasing the PIT rate to 20% and simultaneously cutting the TC threshold to zero (Figure 5.19, Panel C, SE (6), see Figure notes) would better align the distributional shape of the tax burden with employees. On top of the PIT rate increase, the TC threshold cut raises the tax burden between about 50% and 150% of AW. This tax reform would reduce tax arbitrage opportunities between the IA regime and standard employment.
6. Aligning the tax burden with employees might require substantial increase in PIT rates which may not be desirable. Increasing the PIT to 30% and cutting the TC threshold to EUR 5 000 is one option for broadly align with the tax burden for employees. A higher PIT rate is needed to compensate for the tax credit of 10% (even when the tax credit threshold is cut to zero). However, exact alignment may not be desirable (given justifying rationale for lower tax burdens among the self-employed).
Hypothetical modelling applying the SE tax rules confirms that raising the PIT rate and cutting the tax credit threshold would significantly reduce the tax burden gap with employment. Using the same methodology from Figure 5.19 to improve comparability between the IA regime and employment (i.e. setting presumptive cost deduction to zero) but applying a hypothetical modelling analysis using the SE tax rules shows that raising PIT to 20%, cutting the TC threshold to EUR 5 000 and aligning the SSC ceilings would significantly reduce the tax burden gap with employment (Figure 5.20). The reform does not significantly change the magnitude of the METRs but rather shifts them to different income levels.
Increasing the PIT rate in the IA regime from 15% to 20% and simultaneously cutting the tax credit threshold from EUR 20 000 to EUR 5,000 would raise total PIT revenues by about 1% and modestly reduce income inequality (by 0.0123 percentage points based on the S80/S20 ratio). According to modelling using EUROMOD, the reform would produce relatively high increases in total PIT revenues in both the bottom and top equivalised household disposable income deciles (Figure 5.21). The result reflects the low PIT paid by many IA taxpayers and the IA regime income distribution whereby most SE earn low incomes in the lower deciles, and a few earn very high incomes in the top deciles.
Self-employed farmers
This section briefly describes the taxation of self-employed farmers. SE farmers are defined as persons working under agricultural individual activity income. SE farmers comprise 1/3 of IA taxpayers in 2019. A detailed examination of the taxation of SE farmers goes beyond the scope of this report, which we leave for future work.
Self-employed farmers have relatively high and varied income sources compared to non-farmer SE. Farmers have higher average SE income and, as such, are more likely to be VAT registered than non-farmer SEs (Table 5.9).
Table 5.9. Average incomes by income source, self-employed farmers and non-farmers
% not VAT registered |
Farming income |
SE income |
Employment income |
Financial income |
Rental income |
Dividend income |
Other income |
|
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Non-farmers (2 609) |
95% |
0 |
1 283 |
287 |
132 |
11 |
29 |
49 |
Farmers (1 040) |
83% |
2 561 |
2 800 |
323 |
165 |
26 |
40 |
879 |
Note: Farmers are defined as persons working under agricultural individual activity income.
Source: OECD analysis of microdata.
The tax rules for self-employed farmers are generous. SE farmers face the same PIT and SSC rates as in the IA regime provided that they are VAT registered (i.e. have revenue above EUR 45 000) and have large agricultural holdings (i.e. at or above 4 Economic Size Units) (Table 5.10). Farmers that are not VAT registered (and are not obliged to register for VAT) are exempt from PIT. Farmers face an SSC rate of 12.52% on their income when the agricultural holding is 4 Economic Size Units (ESUs) or greater. They also have an SSC base of 90% of taxable income and an annual SSC cap applies. Farmers below the VAT registration threshold face the same SSC rate of 12.52% but the SSC base is narrower at 12 MMS and there is no SSC cap. Small farmers with agricultural holdings (i.e. less than 4 ESUs) are not subject to SSCs but are subject to health SSCs.
Table 5.10. Summary of self-employment tax rules for farmers
Size of agricultural holding |
VAT registered |
Non-VAT registered |
---|---|---|
PIT |
||
-PIT rules apply as per IA regime |
-Exempt from PIT |
|
SSCs |
||
> 4 ESU |
-SSC rate is 12.52% -SSC base is 90% of taxable income -SSC annual cap applies |
-SSC rate is 12.52% -SSC base is 12 MMS |
< 4 ESU |
-Do not pay SSCs |
|
Health SSCs |
||
> 4 ESU |
-SSC rate is 6.98% -SSC base is 90% of taxable income before the deduction of SSCs -SSC annual cap applies |
|
> 2 ESU |
-SSC rate is 6.98% -SSC base is MMS |
|
< 2 ESU |
-SSC rate is 2.33% -SSC base is MMS |
Note: Farmers are defined as persons working under agricultural individual activity income. Agricultural tax rules relate to the year 2022. Non-VAT registered refers to persons that are not registered for VAT and are not obliged to register for VAT. ESU refers to economic size units.
Source: OECD analysis of IBFD database.
Most farmers will be exempt from PIT and face narrowed SSC bases. Since most SE farmers are not VAT registered (Table 5.9), a majority of SE farmers will be exempt from PIT and face a narrowed SSC base (relative to SE farmers that are VAT registered). Farmers that are not VAT registered and have smaller agricultural holdings (i.e. less than 4 ESUs) will face even lower tax burdens (as they are exempt from PIT and SSCs and only pay health SSCs on the MMS, see Table 5.10).
Self-employed farmers pay relatively less PIT as a share of total income. An indication of the reduced PIT burden (albeit somewhat crude) faced by farmers can be obtained by comparing the PIT paid as a share of total income across a range of income sources (including employment income, self-employment income, dividend income and others) on the tax records (Figure 5.22).9 The data show that, compared to non-farmer SEs, farmers pay less PIT as a share of total income. As further investigation of the SE farmer tax burden goes beyond the scope of this report, we leave this for future work.
Closely-held corporations
Closely-held corporation modelling framework
An unincorporated individual can organise as an incorporated business and choose the form to realise their return. Drawing from a hypothetical modelling framework, this section provides observations on the tax-induced incentives to incorporate as a closely-held corporation and the choice between distributing profits as dividends and drawing profits as a salary relative to self-employment. The tax system plays a role in producing tax incentives between different business forms. The SE can choose to incorporate their business or not (note that incorporated businesses aimed at the SE in Lithuania include sole proprietorships and small partnerships). Since this is a discrete decision, the tax-induced incentive faced by the SE is well-captured by the average effective tax rate. For employees and unincorporated businesses, income is taxed as active (labour or individual) income. On the other hand, individuals who organise as incorporated businesses can choose the form to realise their returns. Labour income can be converted into capital income, such as dividends or capital gains. An individual that incorporates their business can become an owner-manager of a closely-held corporation. In closely-held corporations (hereafter corporations), profits can be distributed as dividends or the owner-manager takes a salary as an employee.
The tax-induced incentives to incorporate can be examined using a hypothetical framework. In the corporation case, profits are net of costs (i.e. the costs of doing business have already been deducted) unlike the IA case where costs can be assumed to equal to the 30% presumed cost deduction. To make profits of the SE comparable with the corporation, IA costs are set to zero (i.e. taxable income is now equal to gross income). The average tax wedge can then be compared between the IA (with adjusted profits) and the corporation under three cases as follows:
1. The company distributes all profits as dividends.
2. An owner-manager draws all profits as a salary.
3. The company distributes x% as a salary and 1-x% as dividends.
In case 1, the average effective tax rate on dividends is a flat 27.75% as calculated based on equation (1) (i.e. the standard CIT rate and the tax rate on dividends are both 15%10).
(1) CIT + [(1 – CIT)*(Dividend tax rate)]
In case 2, the tax wedge is the same as for an employee.11 In case 3, the average tax wedge is a weighted average of the tax wedge on salary and the tax burden on dividends.
The hypothetical framework makes several assumptions and should be interpreted with caution. A limitation of the analysis is that it compares the IA who pay SSCs (and will eventually receive SSC benefits in the future) with owner-managers who receive company profits in dividends and do not pay SSCs (and will not receive SSC benefits in the future). Given the tax advantages of SSC benefits, SE may be even more preferable to incorporation. If however the owner-manager pays herself a salary as an employee and distributes the remaining profit as dividends, the comparison remains consistent. A further limitation is that closely-held corporations do not have to distribute profits as dividends immediately but can instead opt to retain profits for distribution in the future.
Standard CIT rate
Closely held-corporations that face the standard 15% CIT rate have a tax-induced incentive to distribute profits as dividends relative to the owner-manager taking a salary. The shaded area in Figure 5.23 represents the set of weighted average tax wedges between taking profits 100% as salary versus 100% as distributed dividends. The tax-induced incentive is to distribute profits as dividends at most gross incomes (Figure 5.23). The incentive to distribute profits as dividends relative to taking a salary rises modestly as incomes rise (i.e. the gap between the average tax wedge on taking a salary and the tax burden on dividends widens). Under these tax incentives, we might expect that most closely-held corporations facing a 15% CIT rate would choose to distribute profits as dividends relative to taking a salary as an employee and that corporations with larger profits would be even more likely to do so.
There is a tax-induced incentive to be self-employed relative to incorporation at middle incomes but not at very low incomes. For an individual who can choose between SE in the IA regime and incorporating their business (at the standard 5% CIT rate and distributing profits as dividends), the average tax wedge suggests the following tax-induced incentives (Figure 5.23):
1. At low incomes (below 20% of the AW), incorporation is preferable. The IA average tax burden is higher due mainly to the SSC health floor.
2. At middle incomes (between 20% and 200% of the AW i.e. half of IA taxpayers), SE is preferable.
3. At high incomes (above 200% of the AW), taxpayers are indifferent between organisational forms.
Reduced CIT rate
A reduced 0% or 5% CIT rate applies to certain micro companies (i.e. those with up to an average of 10 employees and annual income of up to EUR 300 000, inter alia) and agricultural companies. The 0% CIT rate is applied for newly registered micro companies only for the first tax period. With regard to eligibility for the reduced CIT rate, the annual income cap of EUR 300 000 (1780% of AW) appears to be quite high based on the IA income distribution (Figure 5.15). This may point to a significant share of companies availing of the reduced rather than the standard CIT rate. Under a 5% CIT rate, the overall tax burden on dividends is 19.25% (applying equation 1), which shifts the overall flat tax rate on dividends downwards (Figure 5.24).
Self-employed taxpayers at low and high incomes have a tax-induced incentive to incorporate and distribute profits as dividends. For an individual who can choose between SE in the IA regime and incorporating their business (at a reduced 5% CIT rate and distributing profits as dividends), the average tax wedge suggests the following tax-induced incentives (Figure 5.24):
1. At low incomes (below 60% of AW i.e. most IA taxpayers), incorporation is preferable (to avoid the SE health SSC floor).
2. At middle-incomes (between 60% and 120% of AW), taxpayers are indifferent between organisational forms (i.e. the average tax wedges are almost the same at 19.20% vs 19.25% respectively).
3. At high-incomes (starting from 120% of AW), there is a gradually increasing incentive to incorporate. Beyond 200% of AW, incorporation is preferred.
Reform options
Consideration could be given to raising the dividend tax rate to reduce tax arbitrage, but further work is needed. Lithuania may consider introducing rules that oblige manager-owners of closely-held corporations to pay themselves a minimum level of salary to somewhat offset the tax-induced incorporation incentives. However, the issue of international arbitrage and the return to capital has not been investigated as part of this report and further work is needed to develop a fuller picture of dividend taxation.
The reduced 5% CIT rate regime could be reviewed in the context of tax arbitrage. Under the reduced 5% CIT rate, incorporating and distributing profits as dividends is tax-favoured at low and high incomes but SE is preferred at middle incomes.
References
[5] Bird, R. and S. Wallace (2004), “Is it Really so Hard to Tax the Hard-to-Tax? The Context and Role of Presumptive Taxes”, in Alm, J., J. Martinez-Vazquez and S. Wallace (eds.), Taxing the Hard-to-tax: Lessons from Theory and Practice (Contributions to Economic Analysis, Vol. 268), Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Bingley, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0573-8555(04)68806-7.
[7] Bucci, V. (2020), “Presumptive Taxation Methods: A Review of the Empirical Literature”, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 34/2, pp. 372-397, https://doi.org/10.1111/joes.12304.
[9] Díaz, J. et al. (2018), “Pathways to Formalization: Going Beyond the Formality Dichotomy: The Case of Peru”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8551, https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-8551.
[3] Engelschalk, M. (2007), “Designing a tax system for micro and small businesses : guide for practitioners”, No. 42435, World Bank Group, Washington, D.C., https://documents.worldbank.org/en/publication/documents-reports/documentdetail/980291468158071984/%20designing-a-tax-system-for-micro-and-small-businesses-guide-for-practitioners (accessed on 11 May 2022).
[6] ILO (2021), Global wage report, https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/@dgreports/@dcomm/@publ/documents/publication/wcms_762534.pdf (accessed on 25 April 2022).
[1] Mas-Montserrat, M. et al. (forthcoming), “The design of presumptive tax regimes”, OECD Taxation Working Papers.
[2] Milanez, A. and B. Bratta (2019), “Taxation and the future of work: How tax systems influence choice of employment form”, OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 41, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/20f7164a-en.
[8] Teixeira, F. (2021), “Case study I: Simplified tax regimes and their impact on social insurance in Uruguay”, in Schüring, E. and M. Loewe (eds.), Handbook on Social Protection Systems, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, https://doi.org/10.4337/9781839109119.00040.
[4] Thuronyi, V. (2004), “Presumptive Taxation of the Hard-to-Tax”, in Alm, J., J. Martinez-Vazquez and S. Wallace (eds.), Taxing the Hard-to-tax: Lessons from Theory and Practice (Contributions to Economic Analysis, Vol. 268), Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Bingley, https://doi.org/10.1016/S0573-8555(04)68805-5.
Notes
← 1. These data, which were provided by Lithuania’s Ministry of Finance, are based on declarations filed by individuals and on behalf of individuals in 2019.
← 2. Employment income refers to payments made in connection with employment relations or relations in their essence corresponding to employment relations, except certain other payments.
← 3. Part-time refers to working less than 12 months of the year. This is therefore different than part-time defined as those working less than 40 hours a week.
← 4. Based on 89 000 business certificate self-employed in 2020.
← 5. In France, presumed expenses are computed with the following rates: 70% for reselling or lodging activities; 50% for commercial and crafting activities and 34% for liberal professions. In Italy, presumed profitability range between 86% and 40% depending on the sector, which implies that presumed expenses vary between 14% and 60% of gross income (Regulation: Allegato 4, Legge 190, 23 dicembre 2014 https://www.gazzettaufficiale.it/eli/id/2014/12/29/14G00203/sg).
← 6. SEE Riga Shadow Economy Index estimates shadow economy in Lithuania at 23% of GDP in 2021.
← 7. Based on a tax record sample of 3,649 self-employed taxpayers in 2019.
← 8. Based on there being no SE business cost information for 83% of 308 000 IA taxpayers and 100% of 89 000 BC taxpayers (i.e. a total of 344 640 SE business with no cost information).
← 9. Note that SSC data for the self-employed are not available in the tax record data at the time of writing of this report.
← 10. The corporation tax rate is 15%. A zero rate or a reduced 5% rate can apply under incentive legislation. The average effective tax rate and marginal effective tax rate are the same assuming profits are excluded on all costs, no other provisions are claimed and there is not CIT allowance.
← 11. Note that comparability with the net SE income could be modestly improved by adjusting the salary paid to the owner-manager to account for the total labour costs faced by the employer. In practice, this could be done by obtaining a new gross income level equal to total labour costs divided by 1.0179 (i.e. gross income = (total labour costs) / (1 + employer SSC + payroll taxes). This simplifying assumption ignores the minimum amounts below the threshold. However, the impact of the adjustment on salary is very modest and it does not change the analysis so it is left unadjusted for simplicity.