This Annex provides more details on the methodological framework employed to obtain the estimates and projections of plastics use, waste and environmental impacts presented in the report. These have been generated by building on the methodology employed in the OECD Global Plastics Outlook publications (2022[1]; 2022[2]).
Policy Scenarios for Eliminating Plastic Pollution by 2040
Annex A. Modelling framework
Copy link to Annex A. Modelling frameworkThe ENV-LINKAGES model
Copy link to The ENV-LINKAGES modelThe OECD’s in-house dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model ENV-Linkages is used as the basis to project the economic activities that drive plastics use. ENV-Linkages is a multi-sectoral, multi-regional model that links economic activities to energy and environmental issues. A more comprehensive model description is given in Chateau, Dellink and Lanzi (2014[3]). The sectoral and regional aggregation of the model as used in the simulations are given in Table A A.1 and Table A A.2, respectively.
Table A A.1. Sectoral aggregation of ENV-Linkages
Copy link to Table A A.1. Sectoral aggregation of ENV-Linkages
Agriculture, fisheries and forestry |
Manufacturing |
---|---|
Paddy rice |
Food products |
Wheat and meslin |
Textiles |
Other grains |
Wood products |
Vegetables and fruits |
Chemicals |
Oil seeds |
Basic pharmaceuticals |
Sugar cane and sugar beet |
Primary rubber and plastic products |
Fibres plant |
Secondary plastic products |
Other crops |
Pulp, paper and publishing products |
Cattle and raw milk |
Non-metallic minerals |
Other animal products |
Fabricated metal products |
Fisheries |
Electronics |
Forestry |
Electrical equipment |
Motor vehicles |
|
Non-manufacturing Industries |
Other transport equipment |
Coal extraction |
Other machinery and equipment |
Crude oil extraction |
Other manufacturing including recycling |
Natural gas extraction |
Iron and steel |
Other mining |
Non-ferrous metals |
Petroleum and coal products |
Services |
Gas distribution |
Land transport |
Water collection and distribution |
Air transport |
Construction |
Water transport |
Electricity transmission and distribution |
Insurance |
Electricity generation (8 technologies) |
Trade services |
Electricity generation: Nuclear electricity; Hydro (and Geothermal); Solar; Wind; Coal-powered electricity; Gas-powered electricity; Oil-powered electricity; Other (combustible renewable, waste, etc.). |
Other business services |
Real estate activities |
|
Accommodation and food service activities |
|
Public administration and defence |
|
Education |
|
Human health and social work |
Table A A.2. Regional aggregation of ENV-Linkages
Copy link to Table A A.2. Regional aggregation of ENV-Linkages
Macro regions |
ENV-Linkages countries and regions |
Most important comprising countries and territories |
---|---|---|
OECD |
Canada |
Canada |
USA |
United States of America |
|
OECD Latin America (LAC) |
Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Mexico |
|
OECD EU |
Austria, Belgium, Czechia, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden |
|
Australia and New Zealand |
Australia, New Zealand |
|
Japan and Korea |
Japan, Korea |
|
Rest of OECD |
Iceland, Israel, Norway, Switzerland, Türkiye, United Kingdom |
|
Non-OECD |
Rest of Latin America (LAC) |
Non-OECD Latin American and Caribbean countries |
Non-OECD EU |
Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Malta, Romania |
|
Eurasia |
Non-OECD European and Caspian countries, including Russian Federation |
|
Middle East and North Africa (MENA) |
Algeria, Bahrain, Egypt, Iraq, Islamic Republic of Iran, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Morocco, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Tunisia, United Arab Emirates, Syrian Arab Republic, Western Sahara, Yemen |
|
Sub-Saharan Africa |
Sub-Saharan Africa |
|
China |
People’s Republic of China, Hong Kong (China) |
|
India |
India |
|
Rest of Asia-Pacific |
Other non-OECD Asian and Pacific countries |
Production in ENV Linkages is assumed to operate under cost minimisation with perfect markets and constant returns-to-scale technology. The production technology is specified as nested Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production functions in a branching hierarchy. This structure is replicated for each output, while the parameterisation of the CES functions may differ across sectors. The model adopts a putty/semi-putty technology specification, where substitution possibilities among factors are assumed to be higher with new vintage capital than with old vintage capital. In the short run this ensures inertia in the economic system, with limited possibilities to substitute away from more expensive inputs, but in the longer run this implies a relatively smooth adjustment of quantities to price changes. Capital accumulation is modelled as in the traditional Solow/Swan neo classical growth model, where economic growth is assumed to stem from the combination of labour, capital accumulation and technological progress.
Household consumption demand is the result of static maximisation behaviour which is formally implemented as an “Extended Linear Expenditure System”. A representative consumer in each region – who takes prices as given – optimally allocates disposal income among the full set of consumption commodities and savings. Saving is considered as a standard good in the utility function and does not rely on forward looking behaviour by the consumer. The government in each region collects various kinds of taxes in order to finance government expenditures. Assuming fixed public savings (or deficits), the government budget is balanced through the adjustment of the income tax on consumer income. In each period, investment net-of-economic depreciation is equal to the sum of government savings, consumer savings and net capital flows from abroad.
International trade is based on a set of regional bilateral flows. The model adopts the Armington specification, assuming that domestic and imported products are not perfectly substitutable. Moreover, total imports are also imperfectly substitutable between regions of origin. Allocation of trade between partners then responds to relative prices at the equilibrium.
Market goods equilibria imply that, on the one side, the total production of any goods or services is equal to the demand addressed to domestic producers plus exports; and, on the other side, the total demand is allocated between the demands (both final and intermediary) by domestic producers and the import demand.
ENV Linkages is fully homogeneous in prices and only relative prices matter. All prices are expressed relative to the numéraire of the price system that is arbitrarily chosen as the index of OECD manufacturing exports prices. Each region runs a current account balance, which is fixed in terms of the numéraire.
As ENV-Linkages is recursive-dynamic and does not incorporate forward-looking behaviour, price-induced changes in innovation patterns are not represented in the model. The model does, however, entail technological progress through an annual adjustment of the various productivity parameters, including e.g. autonomous energy efficiency and labour productivity improvements. Furthermore, as production with new capital has a relatively large degree of flexibility in choice of inputs, existing technologies can diffuse to other firms. Thus, within the CGE framework, firms choose the least-cost combination of inputs, given the existing state of technology. The capital vintage structure also ensures that such flexibilities are larger in the long run than in the short run.
Estimates and projections for plastics use, plastic waste and end-of-life fates
Copy link to Estimates and projections for plastics use, plastic waste and end-of-life fatesThe ENV-Linkages model has been extended to include plastics production and use, for both primary and secondary (recycled) plastics. The plastics production and use data is presented in million metric tonnes (Mt) and plastics use is split by region, polymer and application. Figure A A.1 presents estimates for plastics use by polymer and application in 2020. Waste estimates and end-of-life fates are derived based on average lifespans by application and country-specific end-of-life shares. Further information on the data sources used to derive the estimates for plastic flows, from production to disposal and mismanagement, is presented in (OECD, 2022[1]).
The projections on the leakage of waste plastics to aquatic environments are made by L. Lebreton (2024[4]), employing a methodology that estimates the amount of plastic waste entering aquatic environments (by region). As explained in more detail in (OECD, 2022[2]), the methodology employs results from a previous study by Borrelle et al. (2020[5]) which estimated leakage of mismanaged plastic waste into rivers, lakes, and the ocean at a global scale. The model computes the probability of releases of plastics (from mismanaged plastic waste produced in a certain region or country) to reach an aquatic environment (rivers, lakes, and oceans).
The model also assesses the mobility of plastics in aquatic environments as well as degradation. The whole-ocean plastic mass budget model presented in (Lebreton and Andrady, 2019[6]) is expanded to a simplified representation of the global aquatic environment. The model differentiates between annual inputs in freshwater and the ocean, allowing floating plastic waste to circulate from one compartment to the other over time. The model also differentiates inputs by polymer types using the OECD ENV-Linkages model estimates and waste projections presented in this report. The likely fate of emitted plastics is determined depending on their density. Additionally, the degradation rates vary across polymers based on laboratory results (Gerritse et al., 2020[7]). The general model framework is presented in Figure A A.2. The methodology is explained in more detail in (OECD, 2022[2]).
Estimates and projections for plastics-related greenhouse gas emissions
Copy link to Estimates and projections for plastics-related greenhouse gas emissionsThe methodology and parameters employed to generate projections on the contribution of the lifecycle of plastics to GHG emissions, on a global level, are detailed in (OECD, 2022[2]). Plastics-related GHG emissions are calibrated based on emission factors for the year 2015 provided by Zheng and Suh (2019[8]), and calibrated over time as described in (OECD, 2022[2]). Only GHG emissions from production and conversion, recycling, landfilling and incineration are quantified. GHG emissions from other stages of the lifecycle of plastics, such as those generated from the open pit burning of plastic waste or from plastics in the environment, are not estimated due to a lack of underlying data.
References
[5] Borrelle, S. et al. (2020), “Predicted growth in plastic waste exceeds efforts to mitigate plastic pollution”, Science, Vol. 369/6510, pp. 1515-1518, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aba3656.
[3] Château, J., R. Dellink and E. Lanzi (2014), “An Overview of the OECD ENV-Linkages Model: Version 3”, OECD Environment Working Papers, No. 65, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/5jz2qck2b2vd-en.
[7] Gerritse, J. et al. (2020), “Fragmentation of plastic objects in a laboratory seawater microcosm”, Scientific Reports, Vol. 10/1, p. 10945, https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-020-67927-1.
[4] Lebreton, L. (2024), Quantitative analysis of aquatic leakage for multiple scenarios based on ENV-Linkages, unpublished.
[6] Lebreton, L. and A. Andrady (2019), “Future scenarios of global plastic waste generation and disposal”, Palgrave Communications, Vol. 5/1, p. 6, https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-018-0212-7.
[1] OECD (2022), Global Plastics Outlook: Economic Drivers, Environmental Impacts and Policy Options, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/de747aef-en.
[2] OECD (2022), Global Plastics Outlook: Policy Scenarios to 2060, OECD Publishing, Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/aa1edf33-en.
[8] Zheng, J. and S. Suh (2019), “Strategies to reduce the global carbon footprint of plastics”, Nature Climate Change, Vol. 9/5, pp. 374-378, https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-019-0459-z.